• Sonuç bulunamadı

View of UPPER BOUNDS FOR RUIN PROBABILITY IN A CONTROLLED GENERAL RISK PROCESS WITH RATE OF INTEREST IS A FIRST - ORDER

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "View of UPPER BOUNDS FOR RUIN PROBABILITY IN A CONTROLLED GENERAL RISK PROCESS WITH RATE OF INTEREST IS A FIRST - ORDER"

Copied!
8
0
0

Yükleniyor.... (view fulltext now)

Tam metin

(1)

6961

UPPER BOUNDS FOR RUIN PROBABILITY IN A

CONTROLLED GENERAL RISK PROCESS WITH

RATE OF INTEREST IS A FIRST - ORDER

Quang Phung Duy1, Foreign Trade University, Viet Nam Thinh Nguyen Huu, Foreign Trade University, Viet Nam Chien Doan Quyet, Soongsil University, Korea

Nhat Nguyen Hong, National Economic University, Viet Nam

Abstract:

In this paper, we study a controlled general risk process where claim is homogeneous Markov chain and rate of interest is a first-order autoregressive process. We assume that claim is homogeneous Markov chain, take a countable number of nonnegative values and rate of interest is a sequence of non-negative random variables what it satifies a first-order autoregressive process. Generalized Lundberg inequalities for ruin probability of this process are derived by the Martingale approach.

Keywords: ruin probability, homogenous Markov chain, controlled risk process, autoregressive process, Supermartingale, Optional Stopping theorem.

AMS 2000 Subject Classifications: 62P05, 62E10, 60F05 1. Introduction

The ruin problem has been studied by many researchers (J. Grandell (1991), H. U. Gerber (1979), S.D.Promislow (1991)). J. Cai (2002) considered the ruin probabilities in two risk models, with independent premiums and claims and used a first – order autoregressive process to model the rates of in interest. J. Cai and D. C. M. Dickson (2004) built Lundberg inequalities for ruin probabilities in two discrete- time risk process with a Markov chain interest model and independent premiums and claims. J. L. Teugels and B. Sundt (1991, 1995) studied ruin probability under the compound Poisson risk model with the effects of constant rate. H. Yang (1999) given both exponential and non – exponential upper bounds for ruin probabilities in a risk model with constant interest force and independent premiums and claims. L. Xu and R. Wang (2006) given upper bounds for ruin probabilities in a risk model with interest force and independent premiums and claims with Markov chain interest rate.

In addition, many papers studied an insurance model where the risk process can be controlled by proportional reinsurance. The performance criterion is to choose reinsurance control strategies to bound the ruin probability of a discrete-time process with a Markov chain interest. Controlling a risk process is a very active area of research, particularly in the last decade; see ( J. Grandell (1991), O. Hernández-Lerma, J. B Lasserre (1996, 1999,2003)), for instance. Nevertheless obtaining explicit optimal solutions is a difficult task in a general setting. Maikol A. Diasparra and Rosaria Romera (2009) obtained generalized Lundberg inequalities for the ruin probabilities in a controlled discrete-time risk process with a Markov chain interest.

1

Corresponding Author: Quang Phung Duy, Foreign Trade University. Address: 91, Chua Lang, Ha noi (100000), Viet Nam. E-mail: quangpd@ftu.edu.vn

(2)

6962 In this article, we extend the model considered by Diasparra and Romera (2009) to introduce homogeneous Markov chain claims and rates of interest as a first-order autoregressive process. Generalized Lundberg inequalities for ruin probability of this process are derived by the Martingale approach.

2. The Model and Basic Assumptions

Let Yn be the n – th claim payment. The random variable Zn stands for the length of the n – th

period, that is, the time between the ocurrence of the claims Yn1 and Yn. Let

 

In n0be the

interest rate process. We assume that Yn, Zn, In are defined on the probability space ( , , ) A P .

We consider a discrete – time insurance risk process in with the surplus process

 

1

n n

U with initial surplus u can be written as

1(1 ) ( 1). ( 1, ), 1

n n n n n n n

UU  IC bZh bY for n . (2.1)

We make several assumptions. Assumption 2.1. Uo u 0. Assumption 2.2.

 

0

n n

I is a sequence of non-negative random variables, where In denotes the rate of interest during the nth period and satisfies

1 W ,

n n n

I  I

(2.2)

 

0

0  1,Io  i 0, Wm n is a sequence of independent and identically distributed non-negative continuous random variables with the same distributive function

 

( ) ( , Wo ) G zP  z Assumption 2.3.

 

0 n n

Z is a sequence of independent and identically distributed non-negative continuous random variables with the same distributive function

( ) ; o( ) . F zP Z  z With F(0) = 0. Assumption 2.4.

 

0 n n

Y is an homogeneous Markov chain, such that for any n the values of Yo are taken from a set of non – negative numbers GY

y y1, 2,...,yn,...

with Yo = yi and

1 : ( ) ( ) ( , , ), ij n j n i i Y j Y pP Y  y Y  ynN yG yG Where 1 0 ij 1, ij 1. j p p    

Assumption 2.5. We denote by C( b ) the premium left for the insurer if the retention level b is chosen, where 0C b( )c b,  . B

The process can be controlled by reinsurance, that is, by choosing the retention level (or proportionality factor or risk exposure) bB of a reinsurance contract for one period, where

min 1

B :b , , bmin

0 1,

will be introduced below. The premium rate c is fixed.

Assumption 2.6. We denote the function h( b, y ) with values in

 

0, y specifies the fraction of the claim y paid by the insurer, and it also depends on the retention level b at the beginning of the period. Hence yh( b, y )is the part paid by the reinsurer. The retention level

(3)

6963 b =1 stands for control action no reinsurance. In this article, we consider the case of proportional reinsurance, which means that

h( b, y )b.y, with bB. (2.3) Usually, the constant bmin in Assumption 2.5 is chosen by

min : min 0,1 ; ( ) 0

bbC b  . (2.4)

Assumption 2.7. We suppose that

 

0 n n Y ,

 

0 n n Z and

 

0 n n I are independent. Assumption 2.8. We consider Markovian control policies

 

1

n n

a ,

 which at each time n depend only on the current state, that is, a (U ) : bn nn for n . Abusing notation, we will 0

indentify functions a : B,where    , Bis the decision space.

Consider an arbitrary initial state Uo u 0 and a control policy  

 

an n1. Then, by iteration of (2.1) and assuming (2.2), it follows that for n1,Un satisfies

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 n n n n l n l l l m l l m l U u ( I ) C( b )Z b .Y ( I )             

(2.5)

The ruin probability when using the policy  , given the initial surplus u,and the initial claim Yoy ,i the initial interest rate Ioirwith Assumption 2.1 to 2.8 is defined as

1 0 i k o o i o k ( u, y ,i ) P (U ) U u,Y y , I i                 (2.6)

which we can also express as

0 1

i k o o i o

( u, y ,i )P Ufor some kUu,Yy , Ii

 

 (2.7)

Similarly, the ruin probabilities in the finite horizon case with Assumption 2.1 to 2.8, are given by 1 0 n n i k o o i o k ( u, y ,i ) P (U ) U u,Y y , I i              (2.8) Firstly, we have 1( u, y ,i )i  2( u, y ,i )i  ... n( u, y ,i )i...,       (2.9)

and with any nN, n(u, y , i)i 1 

  . (2.10)

Thus, from (2.7) and (2.8), we obtain

n i i n lim ( u, y ,i ) ( u, y ,i ).      

We denote by  the policy space. A control policy  is said to be optimal if for any * initial (Yo, Io) = (yi , i), we have

*

i i

(u, y , i) (u, y , i)

 

   for all    .

(4)

6964 We now construct upper bounds for ruin probabilities is the martingale approach. To this

end, let

1 1 1 n n n i i V U I  

 with n , be the so-called discounted risk process. The ruin 1 probabilities n

 in (2.8) associated to the

V nn, 1, 2,...

are

1 ( , , ) 0 , , . n n o i k o o o i o k u y i P V U u Y y I i             

In the classical risk model, process

1

o n

R U n

e

 is a martingale. However, for our model (2.5), there is no constant r such that 0

 

1

n

rU n

e

 is a martingale. Still, there exits a constant 0 r such that

 

1 n rV n e

is a supermartingale, which allows us to derive probability inequalities by the optional stopping theorem. Such a constant is defined in the following Lemmas.

Lemma 3.1. Let model (2.5) satisfy assumptions 2.1 to 2.8. Assume that for each

1, 2,..., ,...

i Y n yGy y y ,bE

Y Y1 o yi

C b E( ) (Z1)   and

1 ( ) 1 0 o i

0

PbYC b ZYy  then there exists a constant RoR bo( ) satisfying

 ( )1 1 1 o R C b Z bY o i Ee  Yy   (2.11) Proof. Define  ( ) 1 1 ( ) t C b Z bY 1, (0; ) i o i f tEe  Yyt     We have

1 1 1 1 (0) ( ) ( ) ( ) 0 i o i o i f  EC b ZbY Yy C b EZbEY Yy  (by ndependence).(2.12)

and the second derivative is

2  ( )1 1 '' 1 1 ( ) ( ) t C b Z bY 0 i o i f tEC b ZbY e  Yy  

This implies that ( )

i

f t is a convex function with fi(0)0 (2.13) By P

bY1 C b Z( ) 1 0Yo yi

0

, we can find some constant   such that 0

1 ( ) 1 0 o i

0 PbYC b Z    Yy  . Then, we get  ( )1 1 ( ) t C b Z bY 1 i o i f tEe  Yy  

 

1 1

1 1 ( ) ( ) .1 1 o i t C b Z bY o i bY C b Z Y y Ee  Y y    

1 ( ) 1

1. t o i e P  bY C b Z Y y      

This implies that lim f ( )i

(5)

6965 From (2.12), (2.13) and (2.14) there exists a unique positive constant Ri satisfying

( ) 0 i i f R  . Let:

 ( ) 1 1

inf 0 : R C b Zo bY 1 o i o i RREe  Yy then Rosatisfying (2.11).

Lemma 3.2. Let model (2.5) satisfy assumptions 2.1 to 2.8. Assume that for each yiGY

y y1, 2,...,yn,...

,

1

1 ( ) 1 (1 1) 0 o i, o 0 PbYC b ZI   Yy I   i and

1

1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) o i, o 0 E  C b ZbYIYy I   i (2.15) there exits  ir 0 satisfying that

 

1

1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) , 1 ikC b Z bY I o i o Ee    Yy I  i (2.16) Then 1 min ir o R   R (2.17)

And, furthermore, for all yiGY

y y1, 2,...,yn,...

 

1

1 ( ) 1 1(1 1) , 1 R C b Z bY I o i o Ee    Yy I  i (2.18) Proof

For each yiGY

y y1, 2,...,yn,...

, let

 

1

1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) ir( ) , , r C b Z bY I o i o l tEe    Yy Ii for t > 0. Then the first derivative of lir( )t tại t = 0 is

' 1 1 1 1 (0) ( ) (1 ) , 0 ir o i o lE  C b ZbYIYy I   i

and the second derivative is

  12 1 1 1 2 ( ) (1 ) '' 1 1 1 1 ( ) ( ) (1 ) r C b Z bY I , 0 ir o i o l t E C b Z bY I e Y y I i                   

This shows that lir( )t is a convex function. From (2.15) implies that lim f ( )ir

t t   .

Let ir be the unique positive root of the equation lir( )t 0on

0; 

.

Further, if 0   ir. However,  

1

1 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) ( ) (1 ) ij , , o j o R C b Z by I R C b Z bY I o i o i j E e Y y I i p E e                     

(by Jensen’s inequality)  

1 1 1 1 (1 ) ( ) o I R C b Z bY o i E e Y y         

Consequentlty, by Lemma 3.1, we have R C b Zo ( )1 bY1 1 o i E e   Yy   . Hence,  

1

1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) , 1 o R C b Z bY I o i o r Ee    Yy Ii  .

This implies that lir(Ro)0. Moreover, Ro  irfor i, r and so 1

,

: min ir o.

i r

(6)

6966 Thus, (2.13) holds. In addition R1 irfor all i, r, wich implies that lir(R1)0. This yields (2.14).

Theorem 3.1. Under the hypetheses of Lemma 3.1 and Lemma 3.2, for all

1, 2,..., ,...

i Y n yGy y y and u then 0 1 ( , , ) R u i r u y i e    . (2.19) Proof With 1 1 (1 ) k k k l l V U I   

 satisfies that

1 1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) l k k l t l t V u C b Z bY I           

(2.20) Let R V1 n n Se . Then   1 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) (1 ) 1 . n n n t t R C b Z bY I n n S S e           

Thus, for any n , 1

1 1, ..., , 1, ..., , 1, ..., n n n n ES Y Y Z Z I I   1 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) 1 1, ..., , 1, ..., , 1, ..., n n n t t R C b Z bY I n n n n S E e Y Y Z Z I I                 1 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) 1 1, ..., , 1, ..., n n n t t R C b Z bY I n n n S E e Y Y I I                     1 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) 1 1 , , ..., n n n t t R C b Z bY I n n n S E e Y I I                   From

1 1 0 1 1 n t t I  

  and Jensen’s inequality implies

  1 1  1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ( ) 1 ( ) (1 ) 1 1 , , ..., , , ..., n n t n n t n n n t t I R C b Z bY I R C b Z bY I n n n n n n S E e Y I I S E e Y I I                                   In addition,   1   1 1 ( ) 1 1(1 1) 1 ( ) 1 1(1 1) 1 , , ..., , n n n n n n R C b Z bY I R C b Z bY I n n n n Ee       Y I I Ee       Y I            1 1 ( ) 1 1(1 1) , 1 R C b Z bY I o o Ee    Y I      . Thus, we have E Sn1 Y1, ...,Y Zn, 1, ...,Zn,I1, ...,In Sn       

This implies that

 

1

n n

(7)

6967 Let Ti min

n V: n 0Ioi

where Vn is given by (2.20). Then Ti is a stopping time and

 

min ,

i i

n T  n T is a finite stopping time. Thus, by the optional stopping theorem for martingale, we get

 

 

1 i R u n T o ES ESe . Hence,

 

 

 

 

 

1 .1 .1 i i i i i R u n T n T T n T T n e ESES ES  

1Ti.1 i

 

1i  ( , , ). R V n i r T n T n Ee Eu y i     (2.21)

where (2.21) follows because 0

i

T

V  . Thus, by letting

n

 

in (2.19) we obtain.

4. Conclusion

We studied a controlled general risk process where claim is homogeneous Markov chain and rate of interest is a first-order autoregressive process. Using Lemma 3.1 and Lemma 3.2, Theorem 3.1 provide a upper bounds for probability( ,u y ii, ) by the Martingale approach. REFERENCES

J. Cai, Discrete time risk models under rates of interest. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences, 16 (2002), 309-324.

J. Cai, Ruin probabilities with dependent rates of interest, Journal of Applied Probability, 39 (2002), 312-323.

J. Cai and D. C. M. Dickson, Ruin Probabilities with a Markov chain interest model. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 35 (2004), 513-525.

J. Grandell, Aspects of Risk Theory, Springer, Berlin, 1991.

O. Hernández-Lerma, J.B. Lasserre, Discrete- Time Markov Control Processes: Basic Optimality Crieria, Springer- Verlag, New York, 1996.

O. Hernández-Lerma, J.B. Lasserre, Further Topics on Discrete- Time Markov Control Processes, Springer- Verlag, New York, 1999.

O. Hernández-Lerma, J.B. Lasserre, Markov Chains and Invariant Probabilities. Birkhauser, Basel, 2003.

Maikol A. Diasparra and Rosaria Romera, Inequalities for the ruin probability in a controlled discrete-time risk process, Woking paper, Statistics and Econometrics Series, 2009.

H. U. Gerber, An Introduction to Mathematical Risk Theory, Monograph Series, Vol.8.S.S. Heubner Foundation, Philadelphia, 1979.

S.D. Promislow, The probability of ruin in a process with dependent increments. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 10 (1991), 99-107.

B. Sundt and J. L. Teugels, Ruin estimates under interest force, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 16 (1995), 7-22.

B. Sundt and J. L. Teugels, The adjustment function in ruin estimates under interest force. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 19 (1997), 85-94.

(8)

6968 L. Xu and R. Wang, Upper bounds for ruin probabilities in an autoregressive risk model with Markov chain interest rate, Journal of Industrial and Management optimization, Vol.2 No.2 (2006),165- 175.

H. Yang, Non – exponetial bounds for ruin probability with interest effect included, Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 2 (1999), 66-79.

ABOUT THE AUTHORS

Quang Phung Duy: PhD. Mathematics, Department of Mathematics, Foreign Trade University Address: 91- Chua Lang, Ha noi, Viet Nam

Thinh Nguyen Huu: MSC Mathematics, Department of Mathematics, Foreign Trade University

Address: 91- Chua Lang, Ha noi, Viet Nam

Chien Doan Quyet: Statistics & Acturial Science, Soongsil University Address: 369 Sang-doro,Sangdo-dong, Dongjak-gu, Seoul, Korea

Nhat Nguyen Hong: MSC Mathematics, Department of Mathematical Economics, National Economic University

Referanslar

Benzer Belgeler

Cerrahi kaba hatlariyla silvian fissürün tam diseksiyonu, temporal ve frontoparietal operkülalarin serbestlestirilmesi, inferior sirküler sulkus ve temporal sternin insizyonu

Mikrosarmal embolizasyonu ile tedavi edilen anevrizmalar karotid oftalmik (n=6), baziler tepe (n=2), baziler fenestrasyon (n=l), posterior kominikan (n=l), orta serebral

(ataworld.atauni.edu.tr) Bu sayfada uluslararası öğrencileri bilgilendirmek ve yönlendirmek amacıyla “Üniversitemiz” başlığı altında Atatürk Üniversitesinin

Kahramanmaraş ve Şanlıurfa ekolojik koşullarında yürütülen çalışmada; Şimal börülce çeşidinde, yedi farklı ekim zamanı (20 Nisan, 5 Mayıs, 20 Mayıs, 5

minimum mean twist angle value was obtained as 0.468 ◦ for sampleB.ThesampleHT-AlNlayerthicknesswas400nmand the AlGaN buffer layer thickness was 700nm. Based on this

Figure 5.2: Time series graphs of Yapi Kredi Bank and Vakıfbank stock prices Table 5.1 presents the Johansen Cointegration Test output for the pair Akbank-Fortis. The

Combining our hierarchy of outer polyhedral approximations with that of inner polyhedral approximations due to de Klerk and Pasechnik [8], we obtain a sequence of improving lower

♦ s lâ n ı orduları ispanyadaki Got Kralı Rodrik’e karsı kazanılan parlak ve kesin zafer* den sonra M ilâdi 724 senesinde Güney Fransaya girdiler; Liyon