• Sonuç bulunamadı

Corporate risk-taking in developed countries: The influence of economic policy uncertainty and macroeconomic conditions

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Corporate risk-taking in developed countries: The influence of economic policy uncertainty and macroeconomic conditions"

Copied!
21
0
0

Yükleniyor.... (view fulltext now)

Tam metin

(1)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Journal

of

Multinational

Financial

Management

journalhomepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

Corporate

risk-taking

in

developed

countries:

The

influence

of

economic

policy

uncertainty

and

macroeconomic

conditions

C¸i˘gdem

Vural-Yavas¸

KadirHasUniversity,Istanbul,Turkey

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Articlehistory: Received20August2019

Receivedinrevisedform27January2020 Accepted29January2020

Availableonline1February2020 JELClassification: D81 E66 G12 G31 G32 Keywords: Corporaterisk-taking Uncertainty Idiosyncraticvolatility Earningsvolatility Competition Europe

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

Using74,974firm-yearobservationscovering15developedEuropeancountriesoverthe timeperiod1999–2017,thispaperexplorestheeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyon corporaterisk-taking.Thefindingsindicatethatfirmsbecomemoreriskaversewithan eco-nomicpolicyuncertaintyshock.Therelationshipisvalidunderidiosyncraticandearnings volatilityriskmeasures,regardlessofwhetherthemacroeconomicconditionisfavorableor not.Moreover,thecompetitionlevelintheindustryisacrucialfactormoderatingtheeffect ofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyoncorporaterisk-taking.Firmsoperatinginconcentrated industriesdecreasetheirrisk-taking.Conversely,firmsoperatinginhighlycompetitive industriesdonotchangetheirrisk-takingwithaneconomicpolicyuncertaintyshock,no matterwhatthemarketconditionis.However,financialconstraintaffectstheriskaversion offirms.Infact,whenthemacroeconomicoutlookisunfavorable,financiallyconstrained firmsdiminishrisk-takingunderallcompetitionlevels.Ontheotherhand,thefavorable stockmarketconditionsencouragemanagersoffinanciallyconstrainedfirmsandreduce theimpactofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyoncorporaterisk-taking.Allinall,theresults supportthenegativeimpactofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyonrisk-taking,conditionedon themacroeconomicoutlookinthecountryandthecompetitionintheindustry.

©2020ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

1. Introduction

Withthedevelopmentofeconomicpolicyuncertainty(EPU)indexbyBakeretal.(2016),whichmeasuresthe policy-relatedeconomicuncertaintyaccordingtothenewspapercoverage,thereisagrowingliteratureonhoweconomicpolicy uncertaintyimpactsthemacro-economyandthestockmarket.Itisagenerallyacceptedfactthatpolicy-relateduncertainty playsacrucialroleindecisionmaking.Studiesshowthateconomicpolicyuncertaintycausesareductionintheemployment rate,investment,andproductionleveloffirmswhichcanbeseenasoneofthereasonsforeconomyslowdown(Bakeretal.,

2016;Bloom,2009;GulenandIon,2016;Kangetal.,2014).Somerecentliteratureindicatethatpolicy-relateduncertainty

adverselyaffectsthebankingactivityaswell,whichalsonegativelyinfluencesthemacro-economy(Bergeretal.,2018;

Bernaletal.,2016;Bordoetal.,2016).Forexample,byreducingtheasset-sideandincreasingtheliability-sidebalance

sheet,policy-relateduncertaintyharmsthefunctionofintermediatingliquidfundproductionofbanks(Bergeretal.,2018). Moreover,recentliteraturedemonstratestheadverseeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyonthebanklevelcreditgrowth

E-mailaddress:cigdem.yavas@khas.edu.tr https://doi.org/10.1016/j.mulfin.2020.100616 1042-444X/©2020ElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

(2)

anddestabilizationofsovereignbondmarkets(Bernaletal.,2016;Bordoetal.,2016).Furthermore,studiesonequitymarkets indicatethatpolicy-relateduncertaintyadverselyaffectsthestockmarketbyreducingstockprices,increasingstockand commoditypricevolatilities(Antonakakisetal.,2013;BakasandTriantafyllou,2018;Bakeretal.,2016;KangandRatti,

2013;LiuandZhang,2015;PástorandVeronesi,2012).

Whilemanystudiesverifytheinfluenceofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyonthemacro-economyandequitymarkets, thereislimitedresearchonthelinkbetweeneconomicpolicyuncertaintyandriskaversioninthecontextofcorporate risk-taking.Uncertaintyplaysacrucialroleinthedecision-makingprocessofindividuals.Manystudiesintheliterature focusontheindividuals’decisionmakingprocessunderuncertainty.Whenitisconsideredatthecorporatelevel,asHillary

andHui(2009)stated,‘firmsdonotmakedecisions,peopledo’.Hence,uncertaintywillhaveanimpactonthedecision

makingoffirms.Priorstudieshavedemonstratedthatpolicyuncertaintyaffectsthefinancingandinvestmentpoliciesof firms,butsurprisinglylittleattentionhasbeenpaidtotherelationshipbetweencorporaterisk-takingandeconomicpolicy uncertainty.Inthispaper,weexaminetherelationshipbetweenpolicy-relateduncertaintyandcorporaterisk-taking.

Thereareseveralreasonswhyeconomicpolicyuncertaintyinfluencescorporaterisk-taking.First,theuncertaintyof futuregovernmentpolicydecisionsincreasesthepolicy-relateduncertaintyexposureoffirmsinfluencingthefirm’srisk perception.Thechangeinthefirm’sriskperceptionaffectscorporatedecisions.Nguyenetal.(2018)showthatthefinancial derivativeusageofafirmriseswithanincreaseineconomicpolicyuncertainty.Firmstrytoprotectthemselvesagainst increasingpolicyuncertaintybyusingfinancialderivativeswhichisanimportantriskmanagementtool.Thefindingsof

Nguyenetal.(2018)supportthefactthatpolicyuncertaintychangestheriskperceptionoffirms.Second,studiesdocument

thatpoliticaluncertaintyincreasesthecostofexternalfinancing(Kim,2019;LiuandZhong,2017;PástorandVeronesi,2012,

2013)whichcouldcausedifficultyinfinancingriskyprojects.Moreover,asaresultofthenegativeeffectofuncertaintyon thefunctionofintermediatingliquidfundproductionandcreditgrowth,banksbecomemoreselectiveintermsoffinancing riskyinvestmentopportunitiesoffirms.Hence,tohavemorefavorabletermsinfinancialagreements,firmsmaypreferless riskyprojects.Finally,thecapitalinvestmentdecreaseswheneconomicpolicyuncertaintyishigh(GulenandIon,2016), whichalsocouldleadthefirmstopicklessriskyinvestmentopportunitiesduringperiodsofhighuncertaintytobeonthe safeside.

Thispaperaimstoexploretheimpactofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyoncorporaterisk-taking.Firmsoperateandmake financingandinvestmentdecisionsinaneconomicandpoliticalenvironmentshapedbythegovernmentandregulatory agenciesthroughpolicychangesinlaw,regulations,andtaxes.Firmsencounterbothpoliticalandpolicyuncertainties.In theliterature,studiesdocumenthowpoliticaluncertainty,whichismostlyproxiedbyelections,impactsfinancingand investmentdecisionsoffirms(AkeyandLewellen,2017;Durnev,2010;Jens,2017;JulioandYook,2012;LiuandZhong, 2017).Ontheotherside,withthedevelopmentofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyindex(Bakeretal.,2016),researchershave startedtoanalyzetheeffectofpolicy-relateduncertaintyonfirms’financingandinvestmentdecisions.Usingacontinuous policyuncertaintyvariableinsteadofanelectionyeardummyprovidesamorecomprehensiveunderstandinginregard touncertaintyeffectonafirm’sdecisions.Electionyeardummycreatesbothinfrequencyanddisregardsthenon-election yearpolicyrelateduncertainties.Hence,economicpolicyuncertaintyindexwhichisbasedonmonthlynewspapercoverage providesabettercoverageforuncertainty.

Gulenand Ion (2016)provide strong evidencethat there is a negativerelationship between theeconomic policy

uncertaintyandthecapitalinvestments.Also,firmsdecreasetheirmergerandacquisitionactivitieswithanincreasein policy-relateduncertainty(Bonaimeetal.,2018).Inperiodsofhighpolicyuncertainty,firmsholdmorecash(Demirand

Ersan,2017;Phanetal.,2019).Furthermore,inadditiontotheincreaseintheusageoffinancialderivatives,Nguyenetal.

(2018)documentthatwheneconomicpolicyuncertaintyishighintheirhomecountry,firmsincreasetheirforeigndirect

investmentlevelincountrieswithlowerEPUthantheircountry.Thesefindingssignaltheriskavoidanceoffirmsinperiods ofhigheconomicpolicyuncertainty.Hence,wehypothesizethatEPUislikelytodecreasetheriskaversionoffirmsand reducethecorporate-risktaking.

Inadditiontotheunconditionaleffectofpolicy-relatedeconomicuncertaintyonrisk-taking,wealsoinvestigatehow themacro-economicoutlookinthecountryinfluencethelinkbetweenuncertaintyandrisk-taking.Bakeretal.(2003)

demonstratethatmovementsinthestockmarkethaveanimpactoncorporateinvestment.Moreover,Boltonetal.(2013)

provideevidencethatduringperiodswithhighexternalfinancingcostsinequitymarkets,firmsdecreasetheirinvestments anddelaytheirpayouts.Infact,firm’sriskpremium,whichiscomposedoftechnologicalandfinancingriskpremiumis sensitivetocashholdingsespeciallyinpoorfinancingconditions(Boltonetal.,2013).Theyclaimthatfirmsshouldtimethe marketfortheirriskyinvestments.Furthermore,usingoilpricechangeasanuncertaintyforfirm’soperations,Guptaand

Krishnamurti(2018)showthatmarketconditionsmoderatetherelationshipbetweenoilpriceandcorporaterisk-taking.

Hence,unfavorableequitymarketconditionsandincreasinguncertaintycausefirmstomitigatetheirinvestments,delay theirpayouts,andbemorelikelytotakefewerrisks.Basedupontheexistingliterature,weexpectthatfirmsbecomemore riskaverseinunfavorablemarketconditionswithanincreasingeconomicpolicyuncertainty.

Besidesthemacroeconomicoutlook,competitionwithintheindustryisanothercrucialfactoraffectingcorporate deci-sionmaking.Competitionimposespressureonmanagement,andmitigatestheagencyproblemsamongstakeholders,which makesitamoreeffectivegovernancemechanismthanthemarketforcorporatecontrolandthemonitoringeffectof institu-tionalowners(AllenandGale,2000;GiroudandMueller,2010).Also,informationasymmetrydiminishesinacompetitive environment;andtheperformanceofmanagementcaneasilybecomparedwiththeperformanceofcompetitors(DeFond

(3)

competitiveindustries,corporategovernancehasnovalue-increasingeffect(GiroudandMueller,2011).Besidesthe dis-ciplinarypowerofcompetitiononmanagers,competitivepressuredecreasesthepricingpoweroffirmsandreducesthe incomeandvariationincashflow(Valta,2012).Raith(2003)theoreticallyshowsthatthemanagerialincentivesdependon thelevelofproductmarketcompetition.AccordingtoRaith’s(2003)model,inhighlycompetitiveindustries,managershave strongerincentivestoreducecosts.Moreover,theidiosyncraticvolatilityofstockreturns,cashflows,earningspershare andsalespershareincreaseinahighlycompetitiveenvironment(GasparandMassa,2006;IrvineandPontiff,2008).Hence, inconcentratedindustries,firmswillbeinamorecomfortableenvironmenttotakemoreriskssincetheyhaveahigher marketpowerandmorecapacitytodealwiththelosses.Weexpecttheriskaversionofmanagerstochangeundersucha powerfuldisciplinaryforceofcompetition.Theseargumentsleadustotheexpectationthatfirmsinconcentratedindustries willtakemorerisks,especiallyunderfavorablemarketconditions.Thus,weexaminethemoderatingeffectofcompetition ontherelationshipbetweenthecorporaterisk-takingandeconomicpolicyuncertainty.

Inadditiontostockmarketconditionsandcompetition,weexpectthateasyaccesstoexternalcapitalmarketswillalso affecttheriskaversionofamanagerasitincreasestheavailabilityofthefree-cashflow.Almeidaetal.(2011)showthat firmsfacingfinancialconstraintspreferinvestmentsthatarelessrisky.Forfinanciallyconstrainedfirms,itwillbehardto findexternalfinancingfortheirriskyprojects,especiallywhenthestockmarketconditionsareunfavorable.Bakeretal.

(2003)documentthatstockpricemovementsinthemarkethaveastrongereffectoninvestmentoffirmsthatareinthe

topquintileoftheKaplanandZingales(KZ)indexwhichisacommonlyusedmeasureoffinanciallyconstrainedfirms.Also, economicpolicyuncertaintyenhancesthecostofexternalfinancinginequitymarkets(PástorandVeronesi,2012).Moreover, economicpolicyuncertaintyreducesthebanks’liquiditycreationandnegativelyaffectsbankcreditgrowth,whichwould aggravatethecostofexternalcapitalthroughthebanklendingchannel(Bergeretal.,2018).Uncertaintyincreasesboththe costofloancontractingandequitycapital(Francisetal.,2014;Lietal.,2018).Furthermore,firmsincreasetheircashholdings inperiodsofhighpolicyuncertaintytomitigatepossiblefinancialconstraints(DemirandErsan,2017;Phanetal.,2019). Allinall,policy-relateduncertaintycreatesconditionsthatmakeittoughtoaccessexternalfinancing,evenforfinancially unconstrainedfirms.Underthecircumstances,itwouldbeinterestingtoexaminewhetherfinanciallyconstrainedand unconstrainedfirmsdivergeintermsofrisk-takingwithariseinpolicy-relateduncertainty,especiallywhentheyoperate underdifferentcompetitionlevelsandunfavorablestockmarketconditions.Basedonthefindingsmentionedabove,we expecttohaveamoderatingeffectoffinancialconstraintsonthelinkbetweeneconomicpolicyuncertaintyandcorporate risk-taking.Wehypothesizethatbeingfinanciallyconstrainedwillaggregatetheimpactofuncertaintyonrisk-taking.

Weusetwomaincorporaterisk-takingmeasureswhicharecommonlyusedinliterature:Earningsvolatilityand idiosyn-craticvolatility(Acharyaetal.,2011;Bernileetal.,2018;Boubakrietal.,2013;Dingetal.,2015;Faccioetal.,2016;Favara

etal.,2017;Gupta,andKrishnamurti,2018;Johnetal.,2008;Koiralaetal.,2018;KonishiandYasuda,2004;Lietal.,2013).

Idiosyncraticvolatilityisakindofcapitalmarketriskmeasure.Itisestimatedbythevolatilityoftheerrortermsofthe four-factormarketmodelincludingFama-Frenchthreefactors(FamaandFrench,1992,1993)andCarhart’s(1997)momentum factor.Studiesshowthatpolicy-relateduncertaintydecreasesthestockpricesandincreasesthestockandcommodityprice volatilities(Antonakakisetal.,2013;BakasandTriantafyllou,2018;Bakeretal.,2016;KangandRatti,2013;LiuandZhang,

2015;PástorandVeronesi,2012).AlthoughEPUincreasesthestockpricevolatility,theidiosyncraticvolatilityusedinthis

paperisameasureoffirm-specificrisk,whichisnotexplainedbythemarketportfolio,andisdiversifiable.Brogaardand

Detzel(2015)statethateconomicpolicyuncertaintyhasmarketleveleconomiceffects,whicharenon-diversifiable.Inthis

case,weareinterestedintheeffectofEPUonthediversifiablefirm-specificrisks.Inadditiontoidiosyncraticrisks,earnings volatilityistheotherrisk-takingmeasureusedinthispaper.Earningsvolatilityisthevariationinfirms’cashflowsand usedasaproxyforthechoseninvestmentprojects.Intherobustnessanalyses,inadditiontoalternativeidiosyncraticand earningsvolatilities,theannualizedstandarddeviationofdailystockreturns,whichisaproxyfortotalcapitalmarketrisk, isusedaswell.Weconsiderthatboththecapitalmarketriskmeasureandrisk-takingincorporateoperationswillprovide amorecomprehensiveunderstandingintherelationshipbetweencorporaterisk-takingandeconomicpolicyuncertainty.

Weaddressthegapintheliteratureregardingtheimpactofpolicy-relateduncertaintyoncorporaterisk-takingand extendtheliteraturebyinvestigatingthisrelationunderdifferentmarketconditionsandcompetitionlevels,forfinancially constrainedandunconstrainedfirms.Sofar,weknowthatoneveryrecentstudyaddressesthelinkbetweenrisk-takingand economicpolicyuncertainty.Tran(2019)providesevidenceonaninternationalbasisthatpolicyuncertaintydecreasesthe corporaterisk-takingmainlyduetoculturaldifferences.HefocusesontheeffectofnationalculturevariablesofHofstede

(2001)ontherelationshipbetweenuncertaintyandrisk-taking.Althoughourmainevidenceontheadverseeffectof

uncer-taintyonrisk-takingissimilar,weextendtheunderstandingofthelinkbetweencorporaterisk-takingandeconomicpolicy uncertaintybyexaminingtherelationunderdifferentmarketconditionsandcompetition.Insteadofnationalculture,we focusonthemoderatingeffectofmacroeconomicoutlookandproductmarketcompetitionontherelationshipbetween uncertaintyandrisk-taking.Moreover,weexaminehowalltheserelationschangewhenthefirmsarefinancially con-strained.Wealsoprovideabroaderunderstandingofrisk-takingbyusingfivedifferentriskmeasuresincludingearnings volatility,totalmarketrisk,andfirm-specificrisk(idiosyncraticrisk).Furthermore,toimproveourunderstandingofhow peoplegetusedtothepastuncertaintyandreacttothecurrentchangeinpolicyuncertainty,weuseeconomicpolicy uncer-taintyshockwhichisestimatedbyGARCH(1,1)model.Weprovidestrongeconometricanalyseswithvariousrobustness tests.Ourfindingsarerobusttoalternativemeasuresforvariables(risk-taking,marketconditions,competition),alternative sampleconstructionandalternativespecificationofmodeltodealwithendogeneity.

(4)

Table1

Sampledescription.

Countries Firms Firm-Years %ofsample AverageEPUshock AverageEPUchange

Austria 46 874 1.17 0.122 0.033 Belgium 87 1653 2.20 0.122 0.033 Denmark 101 1919 2.56 0.122 0.033 Finland 109 2071 2.76 0.122 0.033 France 644 12236 16.32 0.160 0.094 Germany 623 11837 15.79 0.169 0.081 Ireland 26 494 0.66 0.219 0.208 Italy 207 3933 5.25 0.145 0.055 Netherland 80 1520 2.03 0.157 0.062 Norway 168 3192 4.26 0.122 0.033 Portugal 47 893 1.19 0.122 0.033 Spain 121 2299 3.07 0.189 0.111 Sweden 380 7220 9.63 0.074 0.014 Switzerland 151 2869 3.83 0.122 0.033 UnitedKingdom 1156 21964 29.30 0.172 0.054 Total 3946 74974 100

Thistablereportssampledescriptionincludingthenumberoffirms,firm-yearobservations,theaverageEconomicPolicyUncertaintyshockandthe 12-monthaveragechangeofacountry’seconomicpolicyuncertaintyindex.

InaEuropeanenvironment,using74,974firm-yearobservationscoveringthetimeperiodbetween1999and2017for15 developedEuropeancountries,andusingcountry,year,andfirmfixed-effectspaneldataestimation,thefindingsindicate thateconomicpolicyuncertaintymitigatesthecorporaterisk-taking.Thissuggeststhatwithanincreaseinpolicy-related uncertainty,managersbecomemoreriskaverse.Thenegativeeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintydoesnotchangewhen weconditionthesamplebasedonthemacro-economicoutlook.Interestingly,whenweconsiderthecompetitionwithin theindustry,theadverseimpactofuncertaintyonrisk-takingbecomesinsignificantforahighlycompetitiveenvironment. Ontheotherhand,firmsoperatinginconcentratedindustriesalleviatetheirrisk-takinginperiodsofhigheconomicpolicy uncertainty.However,financiallyconstrainedfirmsdiminishtheir-risktakingforalllevelsofcompetitionwhenthestock marketisbearish,whichsupportstheviewthatfinanciallyconstrainedfirmshavedifficultyaccessingexternalfinancing whenmarketconditionsareunfavorable.

Thispapercontributestotheliteratureinseveralways.Themaincontributionofthispapertotheliteratureistoexplore theeffectofpolicy-relatedeconomicuncertaintyoncorporaterisk-taking.Weextendourunderstandingofhowthe eco-nomicpolicyuncertaintyimpactsrisk-takingbyinvestigatingtherelationunderamacro-economicoutlookandproduct marketcompetition.Specifically,ourcontributiontotheliteratureistoexplorehowtheeconomicpolicyuncertaintyaffects corporaterisk-takingwhenmacro-economicconditionsarefavorableandunfavorable.Tothebestofourknowledge,thiswill bethefirststudyinvestigatingtheeffectofpolicy-relatedeconomicuncertaintyonriskaversioninthecontextofcorporate risk-takingfromtheperspectiveofmacro-economicoutlookandcompetitionwithintheindustry.Next,thisstudyextends ourunderstandingofhowpeoplegetusedtothepastuncertaintyandreacttothecurrentchangeinpolicyuncertaintyby usingEPUshockinsteadofusingsimpleaverageEPUchange.

Finally,thisstudyextendstheliteraturebyexaminingtheimpactofacountry-levelvariableoncorporaterisk-taking. Previousliteraturemostlyfocusesonfirm-levelcharacteristicssuchasculture(Lietal.,2013),CEOgender(Faccioetal., 2016),boarddiversity(Bernileetal.,2018),ownershipstructure(Boubakrietal.,2013),largeshareholderdiversification

(Bauguessetal.,2012),debtenforcement(Favaraetal.,2017),employee’sriskattitude(GuanandTang,2018)andcorporate

governance(Johnetal.,2008).Thisstudyfocusesonacountry-levelfactor,namelypolicy-relatedeconomicuncertainty, asarisk-takingdeterminantunderdifferentmarketconditionsandcompetitionlevelsforbothfinanciallyconstrainedand unconstrainedfirms.

Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows:Section2presentsthedataandtheempiricalmodel.InSection3,wepresent theresults,andthefollowingsectionprovidestherobustnesschecks.Section5summarizesthefindingsandconcludes.

2. Dataandempiricalmethod 2.1. Data

AsreportedinTable1,thesamplecovers15developedEuropeancountries,spanning1999–2017.Westudythelink betweeneconomicpolicyuncertaintyandcorporaterisk-takinginaEuropeancontextforthefollowingreasons.First,even thoughthereisagrowingliteratureoneconomicpolicyuncertaintysinceBakeretal.(2016)havedevelopedtheindex, mostempiricalstudiesfocusonAmericanfirms.ResearchontheeffectofEPUonEuropeanfirmsremainsrelativelyscarce. Second,althoughthesampleconsistsofcountriesfromtheEuropeanUnionexceptforSwitzerlandandNorway,andthe ideaofanintegratedEuropemainlyaimedateconomicintegration,differencesineconomicpoliciesofthemembersofthe

(5)

EuropeanUnionareinevitablyexistent.1Infact,theaverageEPUshockrangesfrom0.074to0.219;andtheaveragenatural logarithmofEPUchangerangesfrom0.014to0.208,whichprovidesenougheconomicpolicyuncertaintychangeamong thecountries.Lastly,thesecountriesdifferintermsoflegalorigins,andapoliticalandbusinessenvironmentwhichallow ustofocusoneconomicpolicyuncertaintydifferencestoexploreinformativepolicyimplicationsfordevelopedEuropean countries.

Thesampleconsistsof3946uniquepubliclytradedfirmswhoseprimarybusinessisnotafinancialsectorwithSICcodes between6000and6999.Themainanalysesarebasedonpaneldataconsistingof74,974firm-yearobservations.Thecountry listandthecorrespondingnumberoffirmsareshowninTable1.TheUnitedKingdomfirmsconstituteabout29.30%ofthe sample.Also,16.32%ofthesampleisfromFrance;and15.79%ofthesampleisfromGermany,whichsuggeststhatthe resultsmaybeinfluencedbytheUK,FrenchandGermanfirms.Nonetheless,therobustnesschecksshowninthefollowing sectionsindicatethatexcludingtheUK,Germany,andFrancedoesnotchangetheresults.

Thefirm-leveldataisgatheredfromThomsonReutersEikonandDatastreamandthecountry-levelvariablesarefrom theWorldBankDevelopmentIndicatorsdatabase.Also,forthecalculationofsomecorporaterisk-takingmeasures,we gatherdailymarketmodelfactorsdatafortheEuropeanmarketfromtheKennethR.Frenchwebsite.Moreover,weusethe EconomicPolicyUncertaintywebsitewhichmainlypresentstheindexdevelopedbyBakeretal.(2016).

2.2. Measuringcorporaterisk-taking

Inthispaper,weusetwodifferentcorporaterisk-takingmeasures.Onerisk-takingmeasuredependsontheidiosyncratic volatilityofstockreturnswhereastheotherrisk-takingmeasureisbasedontheearningsvolatility.

Toestimatetheidiosyncraticvolatility,weuseafour-factormarketmodel,includingFama-Frenchthreefactors(Fama

andFrench,1992,1993,1996,2012)andCarhart’s(1997)momentumfactor.Themarketmodelwefitindividualstocksinto

canbeexpressedas, Ri,t−rf,t=˛i,t+ˇ1i,t



MRKTt−rf,t



+ˇ2i,tSMBt+ˇ3i,tHMLt+ˇ4i,tWMLt+εi,t (1) Thefour-factormarketmodelincludesthemarketexcessreturnovertherisk-freerate,thereturndifferencebetween thesmallandbigsizeportfolios,thereturndifferencebetweenthehighandlow-valueportfolios,andfinallythereturn differencebetweenthewinners’andthelosers’portfolios.

FollowingtheprocedureoutlinedinFu(2009);GasparandMassa(2006)andXuandMalkiel(2003),weestimate idiosyn-craticvolatilityasfollows:Foreachmonthandforeachstock,werunatime-seriesregressionoftheprevious12months’ dailyexcessstockreturnsonfourfactors.Then,forthecurrentmonth,wefittheresultingbetaestimatestothedailyreturns andobtaintheresiduals.Themethodusesout-of-sampleforecastingforbetaestimates.Also,weusea12monthsrolling windowfortheregressionsofeachmonth.Theidiosyncraticvolatilitymeasureisthestandarddeviationoftheseresiduals acrossalldaysandallmonthsforayearwhichwecallRISK1.

Theothercorporaterisk-takingmeasureisearningsvolatility.Manystudiesusetheearningsvolatilityasacorporate risk-takingmeasure(GuptaandKrishnamurti,2018;Koiralaetal.,2018;Favaraetal.,2017;Faccioetal.,2016;Dingetal.,

2015;Boubakrietal.,2013;Lietal.,2013;Acharyaetal.,2011;Johnetal.,2008).FollowingGuptaandKrishnamurti(2018)

andKoiralaetal.(2018),wetakeoperatingearnings,estimatedbytheearningsbeforeinterest,taxes,depreciation,and

amortizationscaledbythetotalasset(EBITDA/TA)ascorporateearningsvariable.

InsteadofusingEBITDAtototalassetratiovolatility,followingJohnetal.(2008),corporaterisk-takingisdefinedas thestandarddeviationofthedifferencebetweenthefirm’searningstototalassetratioandthecountryaverageearnings tototalassetratioforthecorrespondingyear.Infact,totakeintoconsiderationthedifferencesbetweenindustry charac-teristics,whichmayaffecttheaverageEBITDA/TAamongtheindustries,wetakecountry-industryaverageEBITDA/TAfor thecorrespondingyear,whichdiffersfromthemethodologyusedbyJohnetal.(2008).Thus,thecalculationofearnings volatilityasarisk-takingmeasurewillbemadeinthreesteps.First,accordingtotheFama-French10industryclassification, foreachcountry,wecalculatetheaverageindustryoperatingearningstototalassetratioforeveryyear.Thatis,overthe sampleperiod,for15Europeancountries,wehave2850averageindustryEBITDA/TAmeasure.Then,wetakeeachindividual firm’sEBITDA/TAdeviationfromthecountry-industryaverageEBITDA/TAforthecorrespondingyear.Finally,weestimate thestandarddeviationofthedifferencebetweenthefirm’searningstototalassetratioandtheaveragecountry-industry earningstototalassetoveraseven-yearwindow.Theestimationwindowcoversthelastsevenyearswithatleastthree yearsofnon-missingobservations.

Wecanexpressthecorporateearningsvolatilitymeasureas,

RISK2=EarningsVolatilityj,t=









1 T−1 T



t=1



Ej,c,i,t− 1 T T



t=1 Ej,c,i,t

2

(2)

(6)

where,

Earningsdeviationsj,c,i,t=Ej,c,i,t=

EBITDAj,c,i,t TAj,c,i,t − 1 Nc,i,t Nc,i,t



n=1 EBITDAn,c,i,t TAn,c,i,t (3)

where,Nc,i,trepresentsthenumberoffirmswithincountryc,industryiandyeart.EBITDAj,c,i,tistheearningsbeforeinterest, taxes,depreciationandamortizationandTAj,c,i,tisthetotalassets.

2.3. Measuringuncertaintyintheeconomy

TheuncertaintyintheeconomyisestimatedbytheEconomicPolicyUncertainty(EPU)indexdevelopedbyBakeretal.

(2016).Theyusenewscoverageofpolicy-relatedeconomicuncertainty.Todeveloptheindex,theytaketwonewspapersfor

eachcountryandcountthenumberofarticlescontainingsomespecifieduncertaintytermsforeverymonth.Thefrequency oftheEPUindexismonthly.InsteadoftakingthenaturallogarithmoftheaverageofEPUindexoverayearwindow,we workwiththeuncertaintyshocksestimatedbytheGARCH(1,1)model,whichgivesthelowestAkaikeInformationCriteria (AIC)scoreamongGARCH(p,q)modelsfor1≤p≤3and1≤q≤3.

Toestimatetheeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshock,wefirstcalculatethechangeinEPUindex,andthenapplythe GARCH(1,1)model.TheGARCH(1,1)modelingframeworkhasameanequationforthechangeinEPUindex,sayuEPU andaconditionalstandarddeviationequation,hu

EPU.FollowingKang,LeeandRatti(2014),wedefinetheeconomicpolicy uncertaintyshock,EPU,as,

EPUShocks=EPU=uEPU

hu

EPU (4)

Thedefinitionoftheeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockallowsustounderstandhowpeoplegetusedtothepast uncer-taintyandreacttothecurrentchangeinpolicy-relateduncertainty.Themonthlyshocksareaveragedoveroneyearto calculatetheannualeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockstomatchourannualpaneldata.

2.4. Controlvariables

Inadditiontoeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockvariable,followingtheliterature,weusecontrolforsomefirmand country-levelvariablestobeshownaseffectiveoncorporaterisk-taking.

First,weusethenaturallogarithmoftotalassetstocontrolfirmsize.Inthecorporaterisk-takingliterature,itisshown thatlargefirmsaremoreriskaversethansmallfirms(Bernileetal.,2018;Boubakrietal.,2013;Dingetal.,2015;Faccio

etal.,2016;Favaraetal.,2017;Koiralaetal.,2018).Thus,weexpectanegativerelationshipbetweenrisk-takingandfirm

size.

Next,wecontroltheleverageeffectbyusingthetotaldebttototalassetratio.Althoughfinancialleverageaffectsthe firm’saccesstoexternalfinance(AlmeidaandCampello,2007),therearecontradictoryresultsabouttheimpactofleverage onrisk-taking.Somestudiesfindapositivelinkbetweencorporaterisk-takingandleverage(Bernileetal.,2018;Boubakri

etal.,2013;GuptaandKrishnamurti,2018).Incontrast,othersindicateanegativeimpactofleverageonrisk-taking(Faccio

etal.,2016;GuptaandKrishnamurti,2018;Koiralaetal.,2018).Later,weusecontrolfortheprofitabilitywiththeratio

ofearningsbeforeinterestandtaxestototal.Firmswithhigherprofitcanbemoreriskaverseastheyalreadyreachtheir high-profitobjectiveandtheyhavelowerearningsvolatility.Lowerprofitabilityfirmsmightincreasetheirrisk-takingto earnmoreprofit(Boubakrietal.,2013).Studiesdocumenttheadverseeffectofprofitabilityonrisk-taking(Bernileetal.,

2018;Boubakrietal.,2013;Faccioetal.,2016;GuptaandKrishnamurti,2018).Tocapturethepossibleagencyconflict

betweenmanagersandshareholders,weusecontrolforthefinancialslack,whichisestimatedbytheratioofcashand shortterminvestmentstototalassets.Itisageneralphenomenonthatmanagerswithhigherfinancialslackcanincrease theirinvestmentsunnecessarilybyundertakingnegativenetpresentvalueprojects(Jensen,1986).Hence,paralleltothe corporaterisk-takingliterature,weexpectapositiveeffectoffinancialslackonrisk-taking(Bernileetal.,2018).

Weusecontrolfortheassetstructureofafirmbyusingtangibility.Assetstructureshowsthefirm’searningsstrategy. Havingenoughplant,property,andequipmentcanalleviatetheriskofinvolvingahigheroperatingleverage(Nguyen,2011). Studiesdemonstrateanegativeimpactoftangibilityonrisk-taking(Faccioetal.,2016;Nguyen,2011).Ourlastfirm-level controlvariableissalesgrowthwhichcapturesthegrowthopportunitiesofafirm.Firmswithhighergrowthopportunities tendtoinvestmore;hence,theytendtobemorerisk-seeking.Although,weexpectapositiverelationshipbetweengrowth opportunitiesandrisk-taking,therearecontradictoryfindingsonthelinkbetweensalesgrowthandrisk-taking(Boubakri

etal.,2013;Dingetal.,2015;Faccioetal.,2016;GuptaandKrishnamurti,2018).

Followingcross-countrycorporaterisk-takingstudies,wealsousecounty-levelcontrolvariablessincethedataincludes countriesacrossEurope(Acharya,etal.,2011;Favaraetal.,2017;GuptaandKrishnamurti,2018,Li,etal.2013).Tocapture thefirm’sgrowthopportunities,weincludeacountylevelproxy,namelyGDPgrowth,whichistheannualpercentage growthrateofGDP.WealsousethenaturallogarithmoftherealGDPpercapitaasacontrolvariable

Allfirm-levelvariablesarewinsorizedatonepercentlevelfromboththetopandbottomofthedistributiontoreduce theimpactofoutliers.Table2displaysthebriefdescriptionsofthevariablesusedintheempiricalanalysis.

(7)

Table2

Variables.

Variable Definition

PanelA:Firmrisk-takingmeasures

RISK1 Annualizedidiosyncraticvolatilityofdailystockreturnsobtainedfromafour-factorFama-French

modelovera12monthsrollingwindowfortheregressionsofeachmonth(out-of-sample forecasting)

RISK2: Stddev(EBITDA/Totalassets–country-industryaverageEBITDA/Totalasset)

RISK3: Annualizedidiosyncraticvolatilityofdailystockreturnsoveraone–yearwindowinafour-factor

Fama-Frenchmodel(in-sampleforecasting)

RISK4: Stddev(EBITDA/Totalassets–countryaverageEBITDA/Totalasset)

RISK5 Annualizedstandarddeviationofdailystockreturns

PanelB:Firm-levelcontrolvariables

Size Naturallogarithmoftotalassets

Leverage Totaldebt/Totalasset

Profitability EBITDA/Totalassets

Tangibility Plant,propertyandequipment/Totalassets

SalesGrowth Thegrowthofnetsales

FinancialSlack (Cashandshort-terminvestments)/Totalassets

Financialconstraintdummy UsingKZindex(Lamontetal.,2001),assignafirmasafinancialconstraintifKZindexofthefirmis higherthanorequaltothesamplemedianKZindex.

Competition(industrylevel) Herfindahl-HirschmanIndex(HHI) PanelC:Countrylevelvariables

EconomicPolicyUncertainty(EPU)shock AnnualaverageofmonthlyEPUshockswhichisdefinedasuEPU

hu

EPUwhereuEPUisthemeanof

changeinEPUandhu

EPUistheconditionalstandarddeviationequationwhichismodelledby

GARCH(1,1)

RealGDPpercapitagrowth AnnualpercentagegrowthrateofGDPpercapita RealGDPpercapita ThenaturallogarithmofGDPpercapita Marketupdummy Ifthemarket’slast-yearreturnisnonnegative Marketdowndummy Ifthemarket’slast-yearreturnisnegative

Thistablepresentsthelistofvariablesandtheirbriefdescriptions.Thedependentvariableinthispaperiscorporate-risk-taking.Weestimatefive differ-entrisk-takingmeasures.Themainrisk-takingmeasuresareidiosyncraticvolatility(RISK1)andearningsvolatility(RISK2).Intherobustnesschecks,we estimatetheidiosyncraticrisk(RISK3)andearningsvolatility(RISK4)withdifferentmethods.Wealsousetotalrisk(RISK5)forrobustness.Themain inde-pendentvariableisEconomicPolicyUncertaintywhichisestimatedbytheEPUshock.Marketconditions,industryconcentrationandfinancialconstraints arethemoderatingvariables.Wealsoincludefirm-levelandcountry-levelcontrolvariables.

2.5. Measuringcompetitionintheindustry

Competitioninthemarketimposespressureonmanagementandservesamonitoringrole,whichreducestheagency conflictsandaffectscorporatedecisions(AllenandGale,2000).WeusetheHerfindahl-HirschmanIndex(HHI)toestimate thecompetitionwithinanindustry.HHIisthesumofsquaredmarketsharesoffirmsintheindustryandcanbeexpressed asfollows: HHIj,c,t= nj



i=1 s2i,j,c,t (5)

wheresi,j,c,tisthemarketshareoffirmi,inindustryj,incountrycforthecorrespondingyeart.Marketshareofafirmis theratioofitssalestoindustrysales.Fortheindustryclassification,weuse3-digitSICcodenottobeeithertoonarrowor toocoarseapartition.AftercomputingHHIforevery3-digitSICindustrywithineachcountryforthecorrespondingyear, wedefinethreecompetitiondummieswithrespecttoHHIterciles:High,mediumandlowcompetition.

2.6. Measuringfinancialconstraint

Inadditiontomacro-economicconditionsthataffectaccesstoexternalfinance,weconsiderfirm-specificcharacteristics thatinfluencetherelianceonexternalfinancing.KZindexdevelopedbyKaplanandZingales(1997)iscommonlyusedin theliteraturetoestimatethefirm’srelianceonexternalfinancing.FirmshavingwithahigherKZindexscorearemorelikely tohavedifficultyinfinancingtheirongoingoperations.FollowingLamont,Polk,andSaa-Requejo(2001),weestimatethe KZindexasfollows:

KZi,t=−1.0019×CashFlowsi,t

Ki,t−1+0.2826×Qi,t+3.1392×Debti,t

TotalCapitali,t−39.3678×Dividendsi,t

Kt−1

−1.3147×Cashi,t

Ki,t−1 (6)

whereCashFlowsi,tisincomebeforeextraordinaryitems,plustotaldepreciationandamortization,Ki,t-1isplant,property, andequipment,Qi,tistheratioofmarketcapitalization,plustotalshareholder’sequity,minusbookvalueofcommonequity, minusdeferredtaxassetstototalshareholder’sequity,Debti,tistotaldebt,Dividendsi,tistotalcashdividendspaid;and

(8)

Table3

Summarystatistics.

N mean min 50th 75th max StdDev.

PanelA:Corporaterisk-takingmeasures

RISK1 74974 0.123 0.000 0.039 0.102 2.210 0.294

RISK2 51701 0.135 0.006 0.053 0.116 2.156 0.282

RISK3 58335 0.162 0.002 0.057 0.132 2.752 0.362

RISK4 51701 0.135 0.007 0.052 0.117 2.154 0.282

RISK5 50755 0.116 0.004 0.046 0.104 1.722 0.233

PanelB:Firm-levelcontrolvariables

Size 58482 12.094 6.273 11.964 13.839 18.253 2.547 Leverage 57862 0.212 0.000 0.176 0.324 1.014 0.202 Profitability 56644 0.042 −1.409 0.096 0.151 0.457 0.253 SalesGrowth 52285 1.176 0.068 1.058 1.188 6.194 0.702 Tangibility 57869 0.228 0.000 0.159 0.345 0.888 0.222 FinancialSlack 58415 0.170 0.000 0.103 0.221 0.890 0.187

PanelC:Countrylevelvariables

EPUshock.. 74412 0.150 −0.169 0.137 0.246 0.791 0.156

EPUchange 74412 0.060 −0.045 0.046 0.091 0.754 0.064

GDPpercapitagrowth 74974 1.704 −8.269 1.954 2.818 25.557 2.022

Ln(GDP) 74974 27.915 25.315 28.343 28.621 28.990 0.935

Thistablereportsthesummarystatisticsofvariablesusedintheanalyses.PanelAprovidessummarystatisticsforcorporaterisk-takingmeasures.RISK 1andRISK3aretwoidiosyncraticriskmeasures.RISK2andRISK4areearningsvolatilitymeasuresandRISK5isthetotalrisk,whichisestimatedby thestandarddeviationofdailystockreturns.PanelBprovidesinformationonfirm-levelcontrolvariableswhilePanelCpresentssummarystatisticsfor country-levelvariables.EPUshockisestimatedbytheannualaverageofmonthlyEPUshockswhichisdefinedasuEPU

hu

EPUwhereuEPUisthemeanofchange inEPUandhu

EPUistheconditionalstandarddeviationequation,whichismodeledbyGARCH(1,1).EPUchangeisthe12-monthaverageofacountry’s economicpolicyuncertaintyindex.Sizeisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassets.Leverageistotaldebtscaledbytotalassets.Profitabilityistheratioof EBITDAtototalassets.Salesgrowthistheyearlygrowthrateofsales.Tangibilityistheplant,property,andequipmentscaledbytotalassets.Financial slackiscashandshort-terminvestmentsscaledbytotalassets.GDPpercapitagrowthandGDParefromtheWorldBankdatabase.

Cashi,tiscash,plusshort-terminvestmentsforfirmi.AfterestimatingtheKZindexforallfirmsforeveryyear,weclassify

firmsasfinanciallyconstrainedwhentheKZindexisgreaterthanthesamplemedian. 2.7. Summarystatistics

InTable3,wereportthesummarystatisticsforthevariablesusedintheempiricalanalysis.

ThemeanandmedianvaluesforRISK1is0.123and0.039,respectively,whereasthemeanandmedianvaluesforRISK2 is0.135and0.053.Bothrisk-takingmeasureshavehighvolatility.Thevolatilityofidiosyncraticriskandearningsvolatility areclosetoeachother,0.294foridiosyncraticrisk,and0.282forthecountry-industryadjustedearnings.Europeanfirms aremoderatelyleveredwithameanof0.212.Salesgrowthhasameanof1.176;andtheprofitabilityoftheEuropeanfirms inthesampleis4.2%.

TheaverageeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockindevelopedEuropeaneconomiesis0.152withavolatilityof0.156.As detailedinTable1,Irelandhasthehighestaverageeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockwithameanof0.219whereasSweden hasthelowestEPUshockwithameanof0.074.

ThepairwisecorrelationcoefficientsofthekeyvariablesaregiveninTableA1intheAppendix.Thecorrelationcoefficients arenothigh,indicatingthatthepossibilityofmulti-collinearityproblemislesslikely.

2.8. Empiricalmethod

Toexploretheeffectofaneconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockonafirm’sidiosyncraticvolatilityandearningsvolatility, weusethefollowingpaneldataestimationmodel,

RISKi,c,t=ˇ0+ˇ1xEPUShocki,c,t+ 8



k=1 ˇ2,kxControlsk,i,c,t+ 14



c=1 ˇ3,cxCountriesc+



ˇ4,ixFirmi + 16



t=1 ˇ5,txYearst+εi,c,t (7)

wheretheRISKiseitheridiosyncraticvolatilityorearningsvolatilitymeasures.Subscriptsiisforfirms,cisforcountries, andtisforyears.Controlsk,i,c,trepresentfirmandcountrylevelcontrolvariables:size,leverage,profitability,financialslack, salesgrowth,tangibility,GDPgrowthandmarketcapitalizationtoGDP.

Themodelincludes countryfixedeffects tocapturethetime-invariantdifferences acrossthecountries.By includ-ingcountrydummies, weaim tomitigate theeffect ofunobserved countrylevel factors.We alsoinclude yearfixed

(9)

Table4

Economicpolicyuncertaintyandcorporaterisk-taking.

RISK1:IdiosyncraticVolatility RISK2:EarningsVolatility

Baseline Marketup MarketDown Baseline Marketup MarketDown

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Variables predicted RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK2 RISK2 RISK2

L.EPUShock – −0.0207** −0.0311*** −0.0303** −0.0176*** −0.0174** −0.0240** (0.0088) (0.0109) (0.0150) (0.0055) (0.0075) (0.0096) L.Size – −0.0262*** −0.0259*** −0.0304*** −0.0395*** −0.0380*** −0.0456*** (0.0043) (0.0045) (0.0065) (0.0043) (0.0049) (0.0057) L.Leverage +/- 0.1035*** 0.0979*** 0.1019*** 0.0580*** 0.0681*** 0.0580** (0.0161) (0.0175) (0.0261) (0.0144) (0.0186) (0.0230) L.Profitability – −0.1726*** −0.1638*** −0.1792*** −0.1575*** −0.1338*** −0.2025*** (0.0147) (0.0186) (0.0226) (0.0134) (0.0165) (0.0211) L.Salesgwth + −0.0057** −0.0033 −0.0065 0.0152*** 0.0172*** 0.0136*** (0.0024) (0.0031) (0.0044) (0.0025) (0.0033) (0.0045) L.Tangibility – −0.0127 −0.0443* 0.0059 −0.0065 0.0042 −0.0211 (0.0211) (0.0241) (0.0303) (0.0187) (0.0186) (0.0277) L.FinSlack + −0.0501*** −0.0514*** −0.0495** 0.0834*** 0.0841*** 0.0826*** (0.0155) (0.0183) (0.0246) (0.0199) (0.0211) (0.0276) L.Ln(GDP) + −0.0051 0.0648*** −0.0896*** 0.0323 0.0368 0.0276 (0.0183) (0.0222) (0.0308) (0.0229) (0.0296) (0.0234) L.GDPgwth + −0.0026*** −0.0003 −0.0040** −0.0015** −0.0016* −0.0017 (0.0010) (0.0013) (0.0017) (0.0007) (0.0009) (0.0011) Constant 0.5994 −1.3594** 3.0034*** −0.3264 −0.4805 −0.1126 (0.5215) (0.6231) (0.8810) (0.6496) (0.8360) (0.6654) Observation 47,108 29,226 17,507 47,108 29,226 17,507 R-sqr 0.4523 0.4727 0.5419 0.6867 0.7026 0.7153

Thistablereportstheeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockoncorporaterisk-taking.Thedependentvariableiscorporaterisk-takingwhichis estimatedbybothidiosyncraticriskandearningsvolatility.Inspecification1,2and3,weuseidiosyncraticriskwhileinspecification4,5,and6,weuse earningsvolatilityasthedependentvariable.ThedescriptionofthekeyvariablesisgiveninTable2.Alltheindependentvariablesareone-periodlagged tomitigatetheimpactofreversecausality.Columns1and4showthebaselineregressionwiththewholesample.InColumn2,3,5,and6,thesampleis classifiedaccordingtothemarketreturninthepreviousyear.Themarketisupifthemarketreturnispositiveinthepreviousyearwhereasthemarketis downifthemarketreturnisnegative.Weusecountry,yearandfirmfixedeffectsinalltheregressions.Errortermsareclusteredonthefirm-level.Robust standarderrorsinparentheses.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1.

effects tocontrolfor aggregatetrends.Todealwiththeomittedvariablebias,weusefirmfixedeffectsin themodel. The independent variables are laggedone-period to deal withthe possiblereverse causality problem. Moreover,we clusterstandarderrorsatfirmlevelanduseHuber-Whitestandarderrorstodealwiththepossibleheterogeneity prob-lem.

3. Resultsanddiscussions

Table4presentstheresultsoftheempiricalmodelgivenbyEq.(7)withregardtotherelationshipbetweeneconomic

policyuncertaintyandcorporaterisk-taking.Specifications(1)to(3)showtheresultsforidiosyncraticrisk(RISK1),whereas specifications(4)to(6)reporttheresultsforearningsvolatility.Specifications(1)and(4)reportthecoefficientsforentire samplewhereasspecifications(2),(3),(5)and(6)documentthecoefficientsforconditionalmodels.Theresultsgivenin

Table4showthatthecoefficientsonbothcorporaterisk-takingmeasuresarenegativeandstatisticallysignificantwithat

least5%significancelevelforconditionalandunconditionalmodels,indicatingadecreaseinrisk-takingwithanincrease ineconomicpolicyuncertaintyshock.Whetherthemacro-economicconditionisfavorableornot,thenegativeimpactof economicpolicyuncertaintyshockonthecorporaterisk-takingisstatisticallysignificant.Intermsofeconomicsignificance, onestandarddeviationincreaseineconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockcausesa0.323unitsdecreaseinidiosyncraticrisk, anda0.275unitsdecreaseinearningsvolatility.

Large,profitablefirmsdecreasetheirrisk-takinginunconditionalandconditionalmodels.Incontrast,leveragehasa positiveimpactonrisk-takinginallmarketconditions.Interestingly,althoughhigherfinancialslackisassociatedwith higherearningsvolatility,theidiosyncraticriskoffirmdecreaseswithafinancialslackincrease.

Tosumup,whetherthemacro-economicconditionisfavorableornot,economicpolicyuncertaintyshockhasasignificant negativeimpactontherisk-taking capacityofafirmimplyingthatmanagerstendtodecreasetheirrisk-takingasthe economicpolicyuncertaintyincreases.Infact,economicpolicyshockissuchapowerfuluncertaintythatmanagersreduce theirrisk-takingevenwhenthemacro-economicconditionsarefavorableinthestockmarket.

Notonlythemacroeconomicconditionsbutalsotheindustrycompetitionlevelcanhaveanimpactontherisk-taking. Totesttheeffectofcompetitiononcorporaterisk-taking,weemploythefollowingempiricalmodel,

(10)

Table5

Economicpolicyuncertainty,competitionandcorporaterisk-taking.

Baseline MarketUp MarketDown

(1) (2) (3)

Variables RISK1 RISK1 RISK1

L.EPUShock*L.HighCompetition −0.0112 −0.0141 −0.0145

(0.0122) (0.0175) (0.0194)

L.EPUShock*L.MediumCompetition −0.0208* −0.0325** −0.0338*

(0.0115) (0.0160) (0.0178)

L.EPUShock*L.LowCompetition −0.0289** −0.0539*** −0.0364**

(0.0129) (0.0186) (0.0184) L.Size −0.0250*** −0.0252*** −0.0294*** (0.0042) (0.0045) (0.0064) L.Leverage 0.1024*** 0.0988*** 0.0977*** (0.0161) (0.0175) (0.0261) L.Profitability −0.1712*** −0.1622*** −0.1814*** (0.0146) (0.0185) (0.0226) L.Salesgwth −0.0060** −0.0035 −0.0064 (0.0024) (0.0030) (0.0044) L.Tangibility −0.0066 −0.0384 0.0106 (0.0213) (0.0240) (0.0304) L.FinSlack −0.0525*** −0.0542*** −0.0527** (0.0153) (0.0180) (0.0245) L.Ln(GDP) −0.0013 0.0729*** −0.0914*** (0.0184) (0.0224) (0.0308) L.GDPgwth −0.0027*** −0.0002 −0.0042** (0.0010) (0.0013) (0.0017) L.HighCompetition 0.0042 0.0016 −0.0035 (0.0059) (0.0082) (0.0087) L.LowCompetition −0.0026 0.0041 −0.0096 (0.0084) (0.0111) (0.0120) Constant 0.4787 −1.5986** 3.0472*** (0.5237) (0.6269) (0.8802) Observations 47,399 29,412 17,604 R-squared 0.4501 0.4692 0.5402

Thistablepresentsthemoderatingeffectofcompetition(industryconcentration)ontherelationshipbetweeneconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockand corporaterisk-taking.Thedependentvariableiscorporaterisk-takingwhichisestimatedbyidiosyncraticrisk.Specification1givesthebaselineregression results.InSpecification2and3,thesampleisclassifiedaccordingtothemarketreturninthepreviousyear.Themarketisupifthemarketreturnispositive inthepreviousyearwhereasthemarketisdownifthemarketreturnisnegative.ThedescriptionofthekeyvariablesisgiveninTable2.Alltheindependent variablesareone-periodlaggedtomitigatetheimpactofreversecausality.Weusecountry,yearandfirmfixedeffectsinalltheregressions.Errorterms areclusteredonthefirm-level.Robuststandarderrorsinparentheses.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1.

RISK1i,j,c,t=ˇ0+ 3



h=1

ˇ1,hxEPUShocki,j,c,txCompetitionh+ 8



k=1 ˇ2,kxControlsk,i,c,t+ 14



c=1 ˇ3,cxCountriesc +



ˇ4,ixFirmi+ 16



t=1 ˇ5,txYearst+ 2



h=1 ˇ6,txCompetitionh+εi,j,c,t (8)

whereCompetitionhrepresentsthethreeHHIdummyvariables.TherearethreeHHIdummiesdefinedaccordingtowhethera firmislocatedinhighHHIindustry,mediumHHIindustry,orlowHHIindustry.WiththedefinitionofHerfindahl-Hirschman index,higher(lower)HHIvaluesindicatethatthecompetitionintheindustryislow(high).Thetwodummyvariablesadded inthemodel(8)willcapturethedirecteffectofhighcompetitionandlowcompetitionontherisk-taking.Theinteraction termbetweentheeconomicpolicyuncertaintyandthethreecompetitiondummieswillgivetheslopeofEPUshockunder differentcompetitionlevels.

Table5displaystheresultsoftheempiricalmodel(8).Specification(1)reportsthecoefficientswhentheentire

sam-pleisused,whereasspecification(2)reportsforfavorablemarketconditions,andspecification(3)forunfavorablemarket conditions.Consistentwiththepropositionthatcompetitionmoderatestherelationshipbetweeneconomicpolicy uncer-taintyandrisk-taking,theinteractiontermhasastatisticallysignificantnegativeeffectonidiosyncraticriskonlywhenthe competitionislowormedium(atleastat5%significancelevel).Infact,forconcentratedindustries,theinteractionterm hasagreaterandmoresignificanteffectthanformoderatecompetitiveindustries.Intermsofeconomicsignificance,fora firmoperatinginaconcentratedindustry,onestandarddeviationincreaseineconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockcausesa decreaseof0.841unitsinrisk-takingwhenthestockmarketisinfavorableconditions,andadecreaseof0.568unitswhen marketconditionsareunfavorable.EPUshockdoesnothaveasignificanteffectonrisk-takinginhighlycompetitive indus-tries.Evenifthemarketconditionsarefavorable,firmsoperatinginhighlycompetitiveindustriesarereluctanttoincrease theirrisk-taking.

(11)

Table6

Economicpolicyuncertainty,financiallyconstrainedfirmsandcorporaterisk-taking.

FinancialConstraint FinancialUnconstraint

baseline upmarket downmarket baseline upmarket downmarket

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

VARIABLES RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1

L.EPUShock −0.0236*** −0.0102 −0.0601*** −0.0237* −0.0302** −0.0336 (0.0078) (0.0093) (0.0139) (0.0126) (0.0140) (0.0262) L.Size −0.0213*** −0.0153*** −0.0247*** −0.0282*** −0.0248*** −0.0394*** (0.0048) (0.0053) (0.0078) (0.0068) (0.0063) (0.0122) L.Leverage 0.0977*** 0.0736*** 0.1014*** 0.1222*** 0.1020*** 0.1049** (0.0194) (0.0207) (0.0326) (0.0227) (0.0199) (0.0413) L.Profitability −0.1211*** −0.1069*** −0.1336*** −0.1163*** −0.0639** −0.1591*** (0.0179) (0.0208) (0.0322) (0.0207) (0.0250) (0.0360) L.Salesgwth −0.0024 −0.0052 −0.0001 −0.0052 −0.0056 0.0129 (0.0036) (0.0048) (0.0077) (0.0043) (0.0039) (0.0098) L.Tangibility −0.0326 −0.0771* −0.0338 −0.0185 −0.0256 −0.0506 (0.0272) (0.0440) (0.0512) (0.0302) (0.0315) (0.0425) L.FinSlack −0.0463*** −0.0357** −0.0485 −0.0599** −0.0607** 0.0081 (0.0159) (0.0170) (0.0306) (0.0292) (0.0289) (0.0557) L.Ln(GDP) −0.0199 0.0057 −0.0220 −0.0379 0.0491 −0.0974* (0.0165) (0.0199) (0.0268) (0.0274) (0.0302) (0.0548) L.GDPgwth −0.0028*** −0.0016* −0.0036** −0.0038*** −0.0022 −0.0073*** (0.0008) (0.0009) (0.0016) (0.0013) (0.0014) (0.0028) Constant 0.9286** 0.1398 1.0299 1.5363* −0.9414 3.3224** (0.4684) (0.5695) (0.7562) (0.7979) (0.8621) (1.5833) Observations 18,566 11,312 6,633 18,562 11,281 6,546 R-squared 0.5031 0.5033 0.5704 0.4992 0.5410 0.5773

Thistablepresentsthenexusbetweeneconomicpolicyuncertaintyshock,marketcondition,financialconstraints,andcorporaterisk-taking.Thedependent variableiscorporaterisk-taking,whichisestimatedbyidiosyncraticvolatility.TheresultsgiveninColumns1,2and3areforfinanciallyconstrainedfirms, whichareestimatedbyusingKZindex(Lamontetal.,2001).TheyassignafirmasfinanciallyconstrainedifKZindexofthefirmishigherthanorequalto thesamplemedianKZindex.TheresultsgiveninColumns4,5,and6areforfinanciallyunconstrainedfirms,whichhavelowerKZscorethanthesample medianKZscore.Marketconditionisalsoconsideredinthespecification2,3,5and6;andthesampleisclassifiedaccordingtothemarketreturninthe previousyear.Themarketisupifthemarketreturnispositiveinthepreviousyearwhereasthemarketisdownifthemarketreturnisnegative.The descriptionofthekeyvariablesisgiveninTable2.Alltheindependentvariablesareone-periodlaggedtomitigatetheimpactofreversecausality.Weuse country,yearandfirmfixedeffectsinalltheregressions.Errortermsareclusteredonthefirm-level.Robuststandarderrorsinparentheses.***p<0.01,** p<0.05,*p<0.1.

Tosumup,thefindingsoftheempiricalmodel(8)giveninTable5indicatethatthecompetitionlevelintheindustry isacrucialfactormoderatingtheeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyonthecorporaterisk-taking.Firmsoperatingin concentratedindustriesareriskaverse.Ontheotherhand,inhighlycompetitiveindustries,economicpolicyuncertainty shocksdonotaffecttherisk-takingofafirmnomatterwhatthemarketconditionis.

Table6reportstherisk-takingbehavioroffinanciallyconstrainedfirms.Financiallyconstrainedfirmsaremorelikelyto

experiencedifficultyinfinancingtheirprojectswhenthemarketconditionsareunfavorable.Specifications(1)to(3)reports thecoefficientsfor financiallyconstrained firmswhereasspecifications(4)to(6)shows thecoefficients forfinancially unconstrainedfirms.Theresultsgiveninspecification(3)showthateconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockhasastatistically significantnegativeeffectat1%levelonrisk-takingoffinanciallyconstrainedfirmswhenmacro-economicoutlookis unfa-vorable.Intermsofeconomicsignificance,onestandarddeviationincreaseinEPUshockcausesa0.938unitsdecrease incorporaterisk-taking.Ontheotherhand,whenthemarketconditionsarefavorable,theeffectoftheeconomicpolicy uncertaintybecomesinsignificant.Thefindingsimplythatmanagersoffinanciallyconstrainedfirmsmayhavedifficultyin findingexternalcapitalfortheirongoingoperations;andhence,theybecomemoreriskaversewithunfavorablemarket conditions.Infact,matchingfinanciallyconstrained andfinanciallyunconstrainedfirmsusingpropensityscore match-ingweprovideevidencethatfinanciallyconstrainedfirmshavelowerrisk-takingscoresthanfinanciallyunconstrained firms.2

Interestingly,whenweconsiderboththemarketconditionsandcompetition,theresultsgiveninTable7inthe spec-ification(4)demonstratethatfinanciallyconstrainedfirmsreducetheirrisk-takingforalllevelsofcompetitionwhenthe marketconditionsareunfavorable.EPUshockhasastatisticallysignificantnegativeeffectonrisk-takingforallcompetition level(atleastat5%significancelevel).Thisisnotacoincidencesincefinanciallyconstrainedfirmsaremorelikelyto experi-encedifficultyingatheringexternalfinancing,especiallywhenthemarketconditionsareunfavorable.Hence,managersof financiallyconstrainedfirmsbecomemoreriskaverseastheeconomicpolicyuncertaintyincreasesMoreover,thenegative effectofpolicyuncertaintyincreasesasthecompetitioninthemarketdecreases.Intermsofeconomicmagnitude,one

(12)

Table7

Economicpolicyuncertainty,competition,financiallyconstrainedfirmsandrisktaking.

Marketup Marketdown

Fin.Const=0 Fin.Const=1 FinConst=0 Fin.Const=1

(1) (2) (3) (4)

VARIABLES RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1

L.EPUShock*L.HCD 0.0149 0.0120 −0.0067 −0.0426** (0.0237) (0.0149) (0.0355) (0.0180) L.EPUShock*L.MCD −0.0310 −0.0267* −0.0370 −0.0646*** (0.0228) (0.0141) (0.0276) (0.0217) L.EPUShock*L.LCD −0.0610*** −0.0223 −0.0446 −0.0704*** (0.0210) (0.0170) (0.0330) (0.0156) L.Size −0.0246*** −0.0153*** −0.0395*** −0.0252*** (0.0063) (0.0053) (0.0121) (0.0078) L.Leverage 0.1015*** 0.0728*** 0.1048** 0.1007*** (0.0199) (0.0209) (0.0412) (0.0328) L.Profitability −0.0641** −0.1076*** −0.1592*** −0.1347*** (0.0249) (0.0207) (0.0361) (0.0320) L.Salesgwth −0.0057 −0.0052 0.0130 −0.0000 (0.0039) (0.0048) (0.0098) (0.0077) L.Tangibility −0.0263 −0.0759* −0.0503 −0.0331 (0.0313) (0.0435) (0.0426) (0.0514) L.FinSlack −0.0598** −0.0356** 0.0087 −0.0486 (0.0287) (0.0171) (0.0558) (0.0305) L.Ln(GDP) 0.0479 0.0045 −0.0999* −0.0250 (0.0301) (0.0199) (0.0552) (0.0265) L.GDPgwth −0.0020 −0.0016* −0.0072** −0.0035** (0.0014) (0.0009) (0.0028) (0.0016) L.HCD −0.0036 −0.0082 −0.0090 0.0009 (0.0104) (0.0081) (0.0162) (0.0081) L.LCD 0.0203 −0.0110 0.0137 −0.0077 (0.0127) (0.0105) (0.0197) (0.0122) Constant −0.9168 0.1823 3.3902** 1.1232 (0.8607) (0.5700) (1.5933) (0.7456) Observations 11,281 11,312 6,546 6,633 R-squared 0.5414 0.5037 0.5775 0.5708

Thistablepresentsthemoderatingeffectofindustryconcentration(competition)intherelationshipbetweeneconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockand corporaterisk-takingalongwiththenexusbetweenthemarketconditionandbeingfinanciallyconstrained.Thedependentvariableiscorporate risk-taking,whichisestimatedbyidiosyncraticvolatility.HCDisthehighcompetitiondummywhereasLCDandMCDarelowandmediumcompetition dummies,respectively.Columns1and2presenttheresultswhenthemarkethasfavorableconditions.Columns3and4showtheresultswhenthemarket conditionsareunfavorable.Thesampleisclassifiedaccordingtothemarketreturninthepreviousyear.Themarketisupifthemarketreturnispositivein thepreviousyearwhereasthemarketisdownifthemarketreturnisnegative.TheresultsgiveninColumns2and4areforfinanciallyconstrainedfirms, whichareestimatedbyusingtheKZindex(Lamontetal.,2001).TheyassignafirmasfinanciallyconstrainediftheKZindexofthefirmishigherthanor equaltothesamplemedianKZindex.TheresultsgiveninColumns1and3areforfinanciallyunconstrainedfirmsthathavealowerKZscorethanthe samplemedianKZscore.ThedescriptionofthekeyvariablesisgiveninTable2.Alltheindependentvariablesareone-periodlaggedtomitigatetheimpact ofreversecausality.Weusecountry,yearandfirmfixedeffectsinalltheregressions.Errortermsareclusteredonthefirm-level.Robuststandarderrors inparentheses.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1.

standarddeviationincreaseinEPUshockcausesadecreaseof1.098unitsinrisk-takingwhenafirmoperatesina concen-tratedindustry.Forhighlycompetitiveindustries,thedecreaseinrisk-takingis0.665unitsinresponsetoonestandard deviationincreaseinEPUshock.Thisdecreaseis1.01unitsforfirmsoperatinginamoderatelycompetitiveenvironment. TheeconomicmagnitudeoftheeffectofEPUshockonrisk-takingisanincreasingfunctionofindustryconcentrationfor financiallyconstrainedfirmswhenthemacro-economicoutlookisunfavorable.Onthecontrary,whenmarketconditions arefavorable,managersoffinanciallyconstrainedfirmscanmoreeasilyfinancetheiroperations;andtheydonotdecrease theirrisk-takingastheeconomicpolicyuncertaintyincreases.

Summingup,inadditiontotheindustryconditions,beingfinanciallyconstrainedisalsoanimportantfactoraffectingthe relationshipbetweenuncertaintyintheeconomyandthecorporaterisk-taking.Managersoffinanciallyconstrainedfirms canreachexternalfinancingmoreeasilywhenstockmarketconditionsarefavorable.Hence,economicpolicyuncertainty doesnothaveasignificanteffectwhenmarketconditionsarefavorable.Ontheotherhand,financiallyconstrainedfirmsare moreriskaversewhenthemarketconditionsareunfavorablenomatterwhatthecompetitionlevelis.Thenegativeeffect ofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyincreasesasthecompetitionintheindustrydecreases.

4. Robustnesschecks

Weconductsomeadditionalteststoensurethatourmainresultsarerobust.Thefirstsetofrobustnesschecksfocuses onthealternatemeasureofrisk-taking.InTable8,theresultsofthefirstsetofrobustnesstestaregiven.

(13)

Table8

Robustnessanalyses:Alternativecorporaterisk-takingmeasures.

Idiosyncraticvolatility Earningsvolatility Std.dev.returns

baseline upmarket downmarket baseline upmarket downmarket baseline upmarket downmarket

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

VARIABLES RISK3 RISK3 RISK3 RISK4 RISK4 RISK4 RISK5 RISK5 RISK5

L.EPUShock −0.0168* −0.0341*** −0.0185 −0.0158*** −0.0128* −0.0236** −0.0684** −0.1228* −0.1189*** (0.0099) (0.0123) (0.0175) (0.0055) (0.0075) (0.0096) (0.0341) (0.0649) (0.0461) L.Size −0.0375*** −0.0367*** −0.0411*** −0.0410*** −0.0402*** −0.0459*** −0.0486*** −0.0389** −0.0873*** (0.0050) (0.0053) (0.0078) (0.0043) (0.0049) (0.0057) (0.0132) (0.0164) (0.0208) L.Leverage 0.1323*** 0.1241*** 0.1245*** 0.0596*** 0.0694*** 0.0608*** 0.3700*** 0.2902*** 0.4602*** (0.0184) (0.0210) (0.0306) (0.0143) (0.0186) (0.0228) (0.0535) (0.0654) (0.0766) L.Profitability −0.1760*** −0.1658*** −0.1904*** −0.1642*** −0.1415*** −0.2077*** −0.5546*** −0.5188*** −0.5981*** (0.0172) (0.0227) (0.0254) (0.0135) (0.0167) (0.0211) (0.0404) (0.0585) (0.0551) L.Salesgwth −0.0046* −0.0028 −0.0046 0.0156*** 0.0175*** 0.0143*** −0.0236*** −0.0254* −0.0156 (0.0026) (0.0033) (0.0048) (0.0025) (0.0033) (0.0046) (0.0087) (0.0143) (0.0118) L.Tangibility −0.0121 −0.0492* 0.0129 −0.0128 −0.0056 −0.0219 −0.0716 −0.1943** −0.0339 (0.0244) (0.0274) (0.0351) (0.0184) (0.0186) (0.0273) (0.0634) (0.0821) (0.0889) L.FinSlack −0.0667*** −0.0737*** −0.0585** 0.0910*** 0.0932*** 0.0867*** −0.2057*** −0.2051*** −0.2496*** (0.0169) (0.0202) (0.0274) (0.0199) (0.0212) (0.0277) (0.0482) (0.0606) (0.0715) L.Ln(GDP) −0.0137 0.0629*** −0.0864*** 0.0261 0.0306 0.0215 −0.1003 0.1924** −0.3282*** (0.0191) (0.0230) (0.0330) (0.0233) (0.0299) (0.0235) (0.0673) (0.0864) (0.1060) L.GDPgwth −0.0036*** −0.0012 −0.0049*** −0.0015** −0.0016* −0.0019* −0.0128*** −0.0004 −0.0276*** (0.0011) (0.0014) (0.0018) (0.0007) (0.0009) (0.0011) (0.0035) (0.0046) (0.0057) Constant 0.9765* −1.1734* 3.0394*** −0.1379 −0.2783 0.0600 6.1710*** −2.1141 12.9580*** (0.5443) (0.6434) (0.9471) (0.6588) (0.8451) (0.6688) (1.8966) (2.4203) (3.0017) Observations 46,212 28,733 17,038 47,108 29,226 17,507 46,336 28,817 17,082 R-squared 0.4341 0.4480 0.5308 0.6826 0.6989 0.7108 0.4371 0.4306 0.6193

Thistablereportstheeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyshockoncorporaterisk-takingforalternativerisk-takingmeasures.Thedependentvariableis thecorporaterisk-taking.Inspecifications1,2and3,weusealternativeidiosyncraticriskmeasure(RISK3),whichisestimatedbyannualizedidiosyncratic volatilityofdailystockreturnsoveraone–yearwindowinafour-factorFama-Frenchmodel(in-sampleforecasting).Inspecifications4,5,and6,weuse alternativeearningsvolatilitymeasure(RISK4),whichisestimatedbythefirm’searningsdeviationfromcountry-industryaverageearnings.Inspecifications 7,8and9,weusetotalriskmeasure(RISK5),whichisestimatedbytheannualizedstandarddeviationofdailystockreturns.Inspecifications1,4,and7,we usethewholesampletoestimatethebaselineregression.Inspecifications2,3,5,6,8,and9,thesampleisclassifiedaccordingtothemarketreturninthe previousyear.Themarketisupifthemarketreturnispositiveinthepreviousyearwhereasthemarketisdownifthemarketreturnisnegative.Columns 2,5,and8givetheresultwhenthemarketconditionsarefavorablewhileColumns3,6,and9presenttheresultsforunfavorablemarketconditions.The descriptionofthekeyvariablesisgiveninTable2.Alltheindependentvariablesareone-periodlaggedtomitigatetheimpactofreversecausality.Weuse country,yearandfirmfixedeffectsinalltheregressions.Errortermsareclusteredonthefirm-level.Robuststandarderrorsinparentheses.***p<0.01,** p<0.05,*p<0.1.

4.1. Alternatemeasureofrisk-taking

Thefirstrobustnesscheckisfocusedonthedependentvariable,corporaterisk-taking.Althoughweusebothidiosyncratic andearningsvolatilitiesasrisk-takingmeasures,wealsotestwhethertheresultsarevalidunderdifferentidiosyncraticand earningsvolatilityestimations.

Inthemainanalysis,weuseout-of-sampleforecastingtoestimatetheidiosyncraticvolatility.Fortherobustnesscheck, weuseanadditionalidiosyncraticvolatilityriskmeasure,whichwillbeestimatedbyin-sampleforecasting.Toestimatethe alternateidiosyncraticvolatility,weapplythefollowingprocedure:

Foreachyear,dailyexcessstockreturnsarerunonthefourfactorsofthemarketmodelmentionedinEq.(1)overa one-yearwindowforeachindividualstock.Thetimeseriesregressionsarerunonfourfactorsifthestockhasatleast30daily observationsinthatyear.Then,wefittheresultingbetaestimatestothedailystockreturnsonthecurrentyearandobtain thedailyresiduals.Thealternateidiosyncraticvolatilitymeasureisthestandarddeviationofthedailyresidualswithinthe calendaryear;andwecallitRISK3.

Themostimportantdifferencebetweenthetwoidiosyncraticvolatilityestimationmethodsisthatthefirstmethoduses out-of-sampleforecastingwhereasthesecondmethodusesin-sampleforecasting.Althoughbothmethodsuse12-month dailydatafortheregressions,thefirstmethodusesarollingsamplefortheprevious12monthswhereasthesecondmethod usesthecalendaryearperiodforeachregression.

Inthemainanalysis,toestimateearningsvolatility,weusethefirm’searningsdeviationfromcountry-industryaverage earnings.Butintheliterature,generally,countryaverageearningsareused.So,wealsocheckwhetherourresultsarevalid whenweestimateearningsvolatilitybyusingthedeviationsfromthecountryaverageEBITDA/TAforthecorresponding year;andwecallthisvolatilityRISK4.

Inadditiontoalternateidiosyncraticandearningsvolatilitymeasures,wealsousetheannualizedstandarddeviationof dailystockreturns.ThislastriskmeasureiscalledRISK5.

TheresultsgiveninTable8showthateconomicpolicyuncertaintynegativelyaffectscorporaterisk-taking.Thus,we concludethattheresultsarevalidunderdifferentcorporaterisk-takingmeasures.

(14)

4.2. Alternatesampleconstruction

Themainsampleincludes15developedEuropeancountries,includingtheUK,Germany,andFrance.Thesample dis-tributiongiveninTable1showsthatfirmsfromtheUKconstitute29.30%;fromGermany15.79%;andfromFrance16.32 %,whichisintotal61.41%ofthesample.ThisraisesthequestionofwhetherthefirmsfromthesethreelargeEuropean countriesdominatetheresults.Thus,toensurethattheresultsarevalidfortheotherdevelopedEuropeancountriesinthe sample,weexcludetheUK,Germany,andFrancefromthesample,andrepeattheempiricalanalysis.Theresultsgivenin thespecifications(1)-(3)inTable9showthateconomicpolicyuncertaintyhasasignificantnegativeeffectoncorporate risk-takingevenwhenweexcludetheUK,Germany,andFrancefromthesample.

4.3. Alternatemeasuresofmarketconditions

Inthemainanalysis,weusepositive(negative)marketreturnsasanindicatoroffavorable(unfavorable)market condi-tions.Weusethreealternatemarketconditionsclassificationforrobustness.

Inthefirstalternateclassification,tomitigatetheeffectofextrememarketreturns,wewinsorizemarketreturnsat5 %onbothsidesinordertosmooththemarketreturnsforthecountriesfirst;andthen,weclassifythemarketcondition asfavorable(unfavorable)whenthemarketreturnisabove(below)zero.Theresultsgiveninthespecifications(4)-(5)

inTable9showthateconomicpolicyuncertaintyhasasignificantnegativeeffectonrisk-takingunderbothfavorableand

unfavorablemarketconditions.

Wealsocheckthelong-runmarketconditionsbyestimatingmarketconditionswiththelasttwoconsecutiveyearsofthe marketreturn.Themarketisinfavorable(unfavorable)conditionswhenthelasttwo-yearmarketreturnsareabove(below) zero.Theresultsaregiveninthespecifications(6)-(7).Thenegativeeffectofeconomicpolicyuncertaintycontinues.In fact,forlong-rununfavorablemarketconditions,thenegativeimpactisgreater.

Oneotherconcerniswhethertakingaboveandbelowzeroisagoodindicatorofmarketconditionclassification.We usea±15%marketreturnasacut-offpointforfavorableandunfavorablemarketconditions.Accordingtotheresults giveninspecifications(8)-(9)inTable9,thesignificantnegativeeffectofuncertaintyonrisk-takingisvalidunderthe newclassificationcut-offlevel.Moreover,whenwetake-15%asthecut-offlevel,theeconomicpolicyuncertaintyismore detrimentaltorisk-taking.Itis-0.0789,whichisthehighestnegativevaluethroughalltheanalysesinthispaper.

4.4. Alternatemodelspecification

Thenestedlevelnatureofthedatausedinthisstudyallowsustouseahierarchicalmodel.Thedataisatfirmlevel, whichisnestedatcountrylevelaswellasindustrylevel.FollowingLi,Griffin,Yue,andZhao(2013),weusethelongitudinal hierarchicalmodel.Thehierarchicalmodelallowsustomitigatetheeffectofunevensampledistributionwithinthecountry level.Theresultsgiveninthespecification(10)inTable9showthatthehierarchicalmodelalsosupportsthenegativeeffect ofeconomicpolicyuncertaintyoncorporaterisk-taking.TheR-squaredifferencebetweenmodel1,whichdoesnotinclude economicpolicyuncertaintyshock,andmodel2,whichincludesEPUshock,isstatisticallysignificantatfivepercentlevel revealingthataddingeconomicpolicyuncertaintytothemodelimprovesthemodel.

4.5. Alternatecompetitionmeasures

Weaddresstheconcernthatthecompetitionmeasureusedinthemainempiricalanalysesisnotagoodproxyforproduct marketcompetition.Followingtheliterature,weusetwoadditionalcompetitionmeasures:Herfindahl-Hirschmanindex basedonassets,andthepricingpowerofafirmmeasuredbypricemargin.

Largefirmscancreatenotonlyentrybarriersfornewfirms(Benoit,1984),butalsobenefitfromtheeconomiesofscales

(BoltonandScharfstein,1990).UsingassetsinsteadofsalesfortheHHIcalculationisanalternatemeasureofcompetition

usedintheliterature.TheestimationprocedureofHHI(assets)isthesameasthecalculationofHHI(sales),butinsteadof usingsales,wewillusetotalassets.

Oursecondalternatecompetitionmeasureisthepricingpower,whichisestimatedbythepricemargin,andmostlyused inorganizationliteratureastheLernerindex.Firmswithahighpricingpowerhavemonopolypowerandfacelowermarket pressure(Lerner,1934).FollowingDattaetal.(2011)andDattaetal.(2013),weusetheprice-costmargintomeasurethe pricingpowerofacompany.Followingtheliterature,weestimatethepricemarginasfollows:

PriceMargini,j,c,t= NetIncomei,j,c,t

Salesi,j,c,t (9)

whereirepresentsforfirm,jforindustry,cforcountryandtforyear.Afterevaluatingpricemarginforeachfirm,for everyyear,wedefinethreecompetitiondummies:Highcompetition(lowpricingpower),moderatecompetition(moderate pricingpower)andlowcompetition(highpricingpower).

AccordingtotheresultsgiveninTable10,bothcompetitionmeasuressupportthenegativeeffectofeconomicpolicy uncertaintyshockoncorporaterisk-takingwhenfirmsoperateinindustrieswherethecompetitionislow.Moreover,the resultsgiveninTable10supportthepreviousfindingsthatfinanciallyconstrainedfirmsbecomemoreriskaverseasthe economicpolicyuncertaintyincreaseswhenthemarketconditionsareunfavorable.

(15)

C¸ . Vural-Yavas ¸ / J. of Multi. Fin. Manag. 54 (2020) 100616 15 Table9

Robustnessanalyses:Alternatesampleconstruction,marketclassificationandmodelspecification.

excludeUK&DE&FR Winsorizedmarketreturn Longrun Longrun- >=15% <=-15% hierarchical

baseline upmarket downmarket upmarket downmarket upmarket downmarket upmarket downmarket baseline

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Variables RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1 RISK1

L.EPUShock −0.0330** −0.0350* −0.0389* −0.0355*** −0.0354** −0.0347** −0.0541* −0.0286** −0.0789*** −0.0237** (0.0134) (0.0181) (0.0199) (0.0105) (0.0166) (0.0135) (0.0323) (0.0139) (0.0279) (0.0102) L.Size −0.0334*** −0.0289*** −0.0452*** −0.0278*** −0.0256*** −0.0300*** −0.0256** −0.0262*** −0.0201* −0.0258*** (0.0077) (0.0073) (0.0116) (0.0047) (0.0063) (0.0054) (0.0116) (0.0056) (0.0104) (0.0006) L.Leverage 0.1221*** 0.1258*** 0.1275*** 0.0980*** 0.0944*** 0.0849*** 0.1277*** 0.0832*** 0.0722** 0.1095*** (0.0268) (0.0297) (0.0388) (0.0172) (0.0290) (0.0197) (0.0480) (0.0230) (0.0358) (0.0092) L.Profitability −0.2162*** −0.2091*** −0.2363*** −0.1701*** −0.1730*** −0.1175*** −0.2017*** −0.1559*** −0.2134*** −0.2640*** (0.0294) (0.0326) (0.0472) (0.0180) (0.0234) (0.0226) (0.0395) (0.0233) (0.0336) (0.0108) L.Salesgwth −0.0020 0.0001 −0.0009 −0.0043 −0.0047 −0.0080** −0.0062 −0.0020 0.0045 0.0014 (0.0042) (0.0046) (0.0076) (0.0029) (0.0047) (0.0039) (0.0074) (0.0040) (0.0067) (0.0030) L.Tangibility 0.0616* 0.0358 0.0611 −0.0282 −0.0056 −0.0022 −0.0173 −0.0297 0.0758* −0.0287*** (0.0355) (0.0380) (0.0465) (0.0233) (0.0332) (0.0298) (0.0692) (0.0295) (0.0406) (0.0057) L.FinSlack −0.0390 −0.0284 −0.0486 −0.0469** −0.0829*** −0.0708*** −0.0272 −0.0505** 0.0034 −0.0758*** (0.0287) (0.0344) (0.0388) (0.0182) (0.0256) (0.0232) (0.0515) (0.0232) (0.0344) (0.0086) L.Ln(GDP) −0.0334 0.0329 −0.0868* 0.0684*** −0.1172*** 0.0547** −0.2479*** 0.0651** −0.1681*** −0.0192*** (0.0353) (0.0473) (0.0469) (0.0223) (0.0376) (0.0264) (0.0634) (0.0319) (0.0431) (0.0014) L.GDPgwth −0.0006 0.0012 −0.0001 0.0004 −0.0069*** 0.0024 −0.0099** 0.0011 −0.0004 0.0015 (0.0014) (0.0019) (0.0022) (0.0012) (0.0020) (0.0016) (0.0045) (0.0016) (0.0024) (0.0010) Constant 1.4408 −0.4100 3.0297** −1.4414** 3.7257*** −1.0539 7.3403*** −1.3731 4.9964*** 0.9803*** (0.9537) (1.2616) (1.2811) (0.6238) (1.0613) (0.7485) (1.7807) (0.8978) (1.2423) (0.0426) Observations 19,347 11,503 7,746 31,883 15,089 19,154 6,471 18,180 8,331 43,039 R-squared 0.5012 0.5430 0.5552 0.4626 0.5449 0.5182 0.6273 0.4858 0.6242 0.1730

Thistablepresentsrobustnessanalyseswithalternativesampleconstruction,marketconditionclassification,andmethodspecification.Inspecifications1,2and3,weuseanalternatesampleconstructionto

mitigatethepossibledominanceofthreelargeEuropeancountries.WeexcludetheUnitedKingdom,France,andGermanysincetheyconstitute61.41%ofthesample.Inspecifications4,5,6,7,8,and9,we

usealternativemarketconditionclassification.Inspecifications4and5,tomitigatetheeffectofextrememarketreturns,wewinsorizemarketreturnsat5%onbothsidestosmooththemarketreturnsforthe

countriesfirst;andthen,weclassifythemarketconditionasfavorable(unfavorable).Inspecifications6and7,weclassifymarketconditionsaccordingtothelasttwoconsecutiveyearsofmarketreturntotake

intoaccountthelong-runmarketconditions.Inspecifications8and9,weuse±15%marketreturnasacut-offpointforfavorableandunfavorablemarketconditions.Inspecification10,weusethelongitudinal

hierarchicalmodeltomitigatetheeffectofunevensampledistributionwithinthecountrylevel.ThedescriptionofthekeyvariablesisgiveninTable2.Alltheindependentvariablesareone-periodlaggedto

mitigatetheimpactofreversecausality.Weusecountry,yearandfirmfixedeffectsinalltheregressions.Errortermsareclusteredonthefirm-level.Robuststandarderrorsinparentheses.***p<0.01,**p< 0.05,*p<0.1.

Şekil

Table 5 displays the results of the empirical model (8). Specification (1) reports the coefficients when the entire sam-

Referanslar

Benzer Belgeler

bezekler stilistik yöntemlerle inccknerek s~n~fiand~nlmglard~r, sonras~nda Le~. olmak üzere 3 farkl~~ evrenin varl~~~~ ortaya konulmu~tur. yy.'a wanan süreçtek~~ Geç Antik

The writings of Seeley, Sidgwick, Acton, Maitland, Figgis, Barker, Oakeshott, Cowling, Laslett, Runciman, Dunn, Skinner and others are studied here in order to indicate how

During the compilation of Pascal source code, if Pascal compiler gener­ ates some errors resulting from the user’s incorrect flowchart design or syntax of the text

Evliya, Se ya hat name’de Vardân’dan sonra 25 kadar kale ve yerleşim ye- rinden söz eder, bun la rı haritada gö- remiyoruz.. Haritada, Vardân’dan sonra Evliya’nın

Her ne kadar, aynı fiil 5651 sayılı İnternet Ortamında Yapılan Yayınların Düzenlenmesi ve Bu Yayınlar Yoluyla İşlenen Suçlarla Mücadele Edilmesi Hakkında Kanun’un

Hepatitis surface antigen (HBsAg) as a forensic marker in establishing the source of blood stains has been evaluated by studying the stability of HBsAg in stains and

Kliniklere göre hastaların memnuniyet düzeyleri incelendiğinde, cerrahi kliniklerde yatan hastaların memnuniyet düzeylerinin doğum ve dahili kliniklerde yatan hasta- lardan yüksek

çıkan (Aksi Seda) ve daha son­ ra neşredilen (Safahatı Kalp) gittikçe daha güzel ve olgunlaş­ makta olduğunu gösteriyorlar­ dı. Bugün tarihe karışmış