• Sonuç bulunamadı

Estimating Hedonic Demand Parameters in Real Estate Market: The Case of Mugla

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Estimating Hedonic Demand Parameters in Real Estate Market: The Case of Mugla"

Copied!
26
0
0

Yükleniyor.... (view fulltext now)

Tam metin

(1)

ESTIMATING HEDONIC DEMAND PARAMETERS IN REAL

ESTATE MARKET: THE CASE OF MUGLA

Ercan BALDEMİR

Cüneyt Yenal KESBİÇ



Mustafa İNCİ



ABSTRACT

The affect of each characteristic of a heterogeneous good on its price can be determined

by Hedonic Price Models. This feature is originated from the assumption of the model that the

price of a heterogeneous good is the sum of the prices of the characteristics constituting that good.

Therefore, marginal prices for heterogeneous goods enter into the scene. In this respect, we

examine the marginal effects of different housing attributes on the selling price of houses in the

housing market in Mugla.

178 observations have been obtained through a questionnaire based on face to face

interviews with randomly selected real estate agencies from the urban districts of Mugla. The

analyses have been carried out by linear, logarithmic and logarithmic-linear functional forms,

which are frequently used in Hedonic Price Models. Considering the structure and features of

Mugla, the estimated coefficients are found to be significant in terms of both the characteristics of

housing and its location (its position, whether it is in-site or not, etc.). As expected, the variables

that positively affect the housing price have been found in all linear, logarithmic, and log-linear

models to be central heating, ceramic bathroom floor, location on the street, satellite TV,

hydrophor pump, modular kitchen, sunblind, solar water heating, front side facing south,

1500-2000 meters to the city center, the number of bathrooms, square meter of housing, and elevator.

Key Words: Hedonic theory, house markets, hedonic price model.

Emlak Piyasasında Hedonik Talep Parametrelerinin Tahminlenmesi:

Muğla Örneği

ÖZET

Hedonik Fiyatlandırma Modeli ile heterojen bir malı oluşturan karakteristiklerin her

birinin fiyat üzerindeki etkisi tanımlanabilir. Bu durum, Model‘in, heterojen bir malın fiyatının,

onu oluşturan farklı niteliklerin piyasa fiyatlarının toplamından ibaret olduğunu varsaymasından

ileri gelir. Böylece heterojen mallar için marjinal fiyatlar söz konusu olmaktadır. Bu bağlamda,

çalışmada Muğla Konut Piyasasında konutların sahip olduğu farklı niteliklerin konut satış fiyatı

üzerindeki marjinal etkisi ortaya konmaya çalışılmıştır.

Muğla ili kentsel kesimde merkez ilçelerde emlak bürolarında emlakçılarla yüz yüze

görüşme suretiyle tesadüfi olarak 178 anket yapılmıştır. Analizler hedonik fiyat modelinde

sıklıkla benimsenen doğrusal, logaritmik ve logaritmik doğrusal fonksiyonlar kullanılarak

gerçekleştirilmiştir. Katsayı tahminleri gerek konutun özellikleri, gerekse konumu (konutun yeri,

site içinde olup olmaması vb.) açısından Muğla ilinin yapısı ve özellikleri dikkate alındığında

anlamlı çıkmıştır. Beklendiği gibi, doğrusal, logaritmik ve logaritmik doğrusal modellerin

Associate Professor, Mugla University, F.E.A.S., Department of Business Administration.



Associate Professor, Mugla University, F.E.A.S., Department of Economics.



(2)

hepsinde konut satış fiyatını pozitif etkileyen değişkenler; merkezi kalorifer, seramik banyo

döşemesi, konutun sokakta bulunması, uydu sistemi, hidrofor, hazır mutfak, panjur, güneş

enerjisi, güney konumlu konut, şehir merkezine uzaklık 1500–2000 metre, banyo sayısı, konutun

metrekaresi, asansör sayısı olarak bulunmuştur.

Anahtar Kelimeler: Hedonik teori, konut piyasaları, hedonik fiyatlandırma modeli.

1. INTRODUCTION

Housing is a ―unique product‖ with three peculiarities (Harsman and

Quigley, 1991:2-3): (1) Complexity: Housing, as a kind of complicated goods,

can meet a great variety of a family‘s demands and be closely related to the

residents‘ activities such as life, work, amusement, etc.; (2) Fixity: Housing is

directly related to urban land in special location. The movement of housing is

basically impossible under the present technological conditions. This means that

the choice of housing involves consideration of neighborhood relations,

distance to the job site and corresponding public service facilities such as

schools, shopping centers, etc.; (3) Durability: This characteristic affects the

new housing market and stock housing market as well. Different from other

common commodity markets, housing market has a corresponding stock

market. Consumers can carry on replacement among new or old houses, choose

building type, community environment, degree of accessibility, and so on, to

meet individual preferences and get the greatest utility. These characteristics

indicate that influential factors of housing price are very complicated and

closely related to housing characteristics. Therefore, investigating the influence

factors of housing price inside the city from the viewpoint of housing

characteristics is a rational approach. In fact, since housing is a kind of

heterogeneous product, and there are obvious differences between housing

characteristics, scholars often establish hedonic price model to carry on

researches.

2. THE ECONOMIC THEORY OF HEDONIC PRICE MODEL

The term ―hedonic‖ is derived from Latin ―hedonikos‖, meaning

satisfaction. To this end, this concept is used in economics to imply for

enjoyment, satisfaction, pleasure or utility achieved with consumption of goods

or services (Kaul, 2006:4-5).

The term hedonic was first used in correcting price indices for quality

(Cowling and Cubbin, 1972:963). This term was used in an economic sense to

indicate that the index was computed taking into consideration not just the

objective aspects but also the qualitative utility obtained from a product (Kaul,

2006:4-5).

Hedonic Price Model depends on the consumer theory of the classical

economics, implying that each of the characteristics of heterogeneous goods

provides a different level of satisfaction or utility for the consumer. The model

suggests that the characteristics of a good meet different needs of consumers,

(3)

and the satisfaction or utility level of the consumers differs with consumption of

each characteristic. That is why this kind of models carries the term ―hedonic‖

in their names with the meaning of enjoyment, satisfaction, pleasure or utility

obtained with consumption of goods and services.

The Hedonic Price Model was first introduced in 1939 by A.T. Court,

an expert of the American automobile industry (Bartik, 1987:81, Goodman,

1998:291). Court regarded automobile price as a function of the automobile‘s

different characteristics, and carried out hedonic price analysis of heterogeneous

goods. His ultimate objective was to structure the price index for the automobile

industry. After that, this method began to expand to other consumer goods, such

as tractors, washing machines, etc. Colwell and Dilmore believed that Haas was

one of the first users of the hedonic price model (the first hedonic model on

agriculture) (Colwell and Dilmore, 1999:620). Haas (1922) used the concept of

―hedonics‖, and set up a simple hedonic price model for farmland, taking the

distance to the city center and the city size as two important characteristic

variables. On the other hand, Ridker (1967) was one of the earliest scholars to

apply hedonic price theory to analyze the housing market. He calculated the

impact of improving environmental quality (such as the elimination of air

pollution) on housing price.

The theoretical foundation of the hedonic price model is generally

regarded as hedonic price theory. American researcher Lancaster (1966) first

came up with a new consumer theory. The theory was expanded from the

consumer theory of classical economics, also known as Lancaster preference

theory. From the product heterogeneity, Lancaster (1966) analyzed the basic

elements that formed the product, and argued that the demand for the product

was not based on the product itself, but on its characteristics. Heterogeneous

goods (especially such as housing) have a number of incorporated

characteristics, and the goods are sold as the gathering of inherent

characteristics. All of these characteristics are variables of the utility function of

the consumer. Therefore, the utility level depends on the quantity of different

characteristics. It is difficult to analyze a market of such goods with the

traditional economic model because it cannot be considered by a single total

price. Consequently, it is necessary to adopt a series of prices (hedonic price) to

express corresponding product characteristics. As a result, the price of the

product is made up of hedonic prices, with each product characteristic having its

own implied price.

On the other hand, American economist Rosen (1976) submitted, within

the context of Lancaster preference theory, the first equilibrium model of

market supply and demand based on product characteristics. Under the

condition of perfect competition market, with maximizing consumer‘s utility

and producer‘s profit as the goal, Rosen (1976) analyzed theoretically the

long-term and short-long-term equilibrium of the heterogeneous goods market.

(4)

The model identifies the goods

(Z

)

as the total of their n

characteristics

(

Z

i

)

.

i

contains

n

characteristics and indicates the quantity of

each characteristic. In this context, Rosen‘s model can be presented as follows

(Rosen, 1976:37):

)

(

Z

i

f

Z

(

i

1

,...,

n

)

(1)

The goods are described by numerical values of Z and provide the

consumers with different packages of characteristics. Moreover, existence of

product differentiation enabled by the presence of diverse characteristics

implies that a wide variety of alternative packages are available. Accordingly,

the demand function can be described with respect to price and characteristics

as follows:

)

,...,

,

(

)

(

z

p

z

1

z

2

z

n

P

(2)

This function reveals the hedonic price regression obtained from

comparing prices of brands with different characteristics. In other words, it

gives the minimum price of any combination of characteristics. If two brands

offer the same combination but with different prices, consumers chooses the

cheaper one, and the identity of sellers does not have any affect on their

demand. In this connection, taking the partial derivatives of Equation 2, the

corresponding effect of each characteristic on the price (hedonic price) can be

expressed as follows:

İ Zi

Z

P

P

(3)

Lancaster and Rosen‘s approaches try to estimate the combinations of

characteristics –measured objectively and affect the utility– that are comprised

of a number of attributes that the consumer appraises. However, these models

have some basic differences. Lancaster‘s model assumes that the goods are

members of a group, and the goods in a group consist of combinations of

characteristics in accordance with the budget constraint. On the other hand,

Rosen‘s model suggests that goods are in preferential order but consumers are

indifferent for the characteristics while buying a combination of goods.

Moreover, each good is chosen from a bundle of brands and consumed in

certain periods of time. Therefore, Lancaster‘s approach is suitable for all

consumption goods while Rosen‘s model is appropriate for only durable

consumption goods.

Unlike Lancaster, Rosen points out a nonlinear relation between the

price and the inner characteristics of goods. Nonlinearity of the price function in

this model implies that the implicit prices are inconstant.

Rosen‘s model includes two different stages. The first stage determines

the characteristics that affect the price of the good and estimates the marginal

(5)

prices for them. This stage develops a price measure but does not directly

provide an inverse

demand function. It only reveals the marginal contributions

of the characteristics to the price. The second stage defines the inverse

demand

function or estimates the marginal demand function through the implicit price

function determined in the first stage.

According to Rosen, the consumer immediately adjusts the budget

constraint for an increase in his/her income, and his/her marginal demand for a

characteristic may change. Rosen assumes that the price the consumer is willing

to pay for a good –or a combination of characteristics– is a function of the

variables that affect consumers‘ pleasure and preferences such as the

consumer‘s utility level, income, age, and education.

Rosen argues that the inverse demand function can be estimated in the

second stage by simultaneous equations using the marginal price as endogenous

variable, and that the inverse demand function is based on the implicit marginal

cost function. However, this identification of the inverse demand function may

be problematic. If the supply of the good has perfect elasticity or the supply of

characteristics is fixed, the marginal price of the characteristics will be

exogenous in the estimation of the inverse demand function. Therefore, Bartik

(1987) opposes Rosen‘s approach to the hedonic price model and argues that

the problem in hedonic estimation is not a result of the interaction between

supply and demand since an individual consumer cannot affect the sellers.

Under a nonlinear budget constraint, the endogeneity of all marginal prices and

the quantity of the characteristics result in hedonic estimation problem. For that

reason, there is no need to include the supply side of the market in the model. In

this regard, the low elasticity of supply of housing in Mugla –as a result of, inter

alia, the scarcity and therefore the high prices of lands for housing– and the

large quantity of the characteristics of housing require that marginal prices of

the characteristics be considered as endogenous. Accordingly, our study focuses

on the first stage of Rosen‘s model and aims to identify the marginal effects of

various characteristics on the housing price in the housing market of Mugla.

3. LITERATURE ON HEDONIC PRICE MODELS IN HOUSING

MARKET

Application of the hedonic price theory to the housing market was, as

mentioned above, first introduced by Ridker and Henning (1967), who analyzed

the effect of air pollution on housing prices. Following this study, a number of

empirical studies appeared in the hedonic price literature regarding the housing

market, a brief list of which may include Kain and Quigley (1970), Straszheim

(1973, 1974), Goodman (1978), Witte, Sumka and Erekson (1979), Palmquist

(1984), Mendelsohn (1984), Blackley, Follain and Lee (1986), Goodman

(1988), Meese and Wallace (1991), Kim (1992), Macedo (1996), Can and

Megbolugbe (1997), Meese and Wallace (1997), Powe, Garrod, Brunsdan and

Willis (1997), Yang (2000), Leishman (2001), Ucdogruk (2001), Bover and

(6)

Velilla (2002), Ogwang and Wang (2002), Wilhemsson (2002), Toda and

Nozdrina (2002), Maurer, Pitzer and Sebastian (2004), Wen, Lu and Lin (2004),

Filho and Bin (2005), Cohen and Coughlin (2005), Yankaya and Celik (2005),

Hai-Zhen, Sheng-Hua and Xiao-Yu (2005), Li, Prud‘Homme and Yu (2006).

The variables and functional forms they used and their findings are

chronologically presented in the appendix.

4. HEDONIC PRICE MODELS FOR THE HOUSING MARKET OF

MUGLA

Data for this study has been gathered for the reference period –May

2007– through a questionnaire of 33 questions on housing prices and 32

characteristics which are considered to have had an effect on them. 178

observations have been obtained through a questionnaire based on face to face

interviews with randomly selected real estate agencies from the urban districts

of Mugla.

These observations consists 100 percent of the population.

This data

has been analyzed through the hedonic price approach. The variables have been

selected with reference to the literature.

Real estate agencies were asked questions regarding the number of

balconies, the number of elevators, the number of houses in the apartment, the

size of the house, the number of rooms, the floor level, the age of the house

(continuous variable), the heating system, the flooring of the living room and

other rooms, the flooring of the bathroom, the material of windows‘ frames,

roof isolation, wall covering, location, structure of the kitchen, satellite TV,

hydrophor pump, parking lot, sunblind, solar water heating, doorman, whether it

is in-garden and in-site, distance to the city centre, direction of the front side,

ground survey, and occupancy (proxy variable).

There are three most frequently used function forms in hedonic price

model: linear, logarithmic, and log-linear. This study utilizes all the three forms

and interprets the common significant variables. The variables have been

analyzed under SPSS 10.0 statistical program, their frequencies have been

determined, and the variables found to be problematic have been excluded from

the analysis.

Table 1 presents the means and standard deviations of the variables.

Average housing price in the City Center of Mugla is 119.240 YTL (New

Turkish Lira). Average number of bathrooms is 1 while that of balconies is 2.

On the other hand, the average number of rooms in the houses questioned is

3.54. The average number of dwellings in an apartment building where a house

in question exists is 11.5 while their average age is approximately 11. In

addition, Table 1 indicates that the houses in the city center of Mugla are on

average 119 meter square and on the 2

nd

or 3

rd

floor. 60 percent of the houses

are located on streets while 48 percent of them are located on corners, and 53

percent of them are with front side to south. 53 percent of the houses are as far

as 500-1000 meters to the city center. 39 percent of the houses are in buildings

(7)

in which owners of the houses live. Furthermore, 93 percent of the houses are

with clay-tile roofs, 54 percent are with central heating system (furnace) while

34 percent of them are heated with stoves.

Table 1: The Mean and Standard Deviation of Housing Prices and the

Variables that are considered to Have an effect on the Housing Prices

Variable

Mean

Std.

Dev.

Variable

Mean

Std.

Dev.

Housing Price

119.24

33.427

Age of House

10.94

7.457

H

ea

ti

n

g

Stove

.34

.474

D

ist

an

ce

t

o

C

it

y

C

en

tr

e

500–1000m

.53

.501

Central (Floor)

.12

.323

1000-1500m

.23

.422

Central

(Apartment)

.54

.499

1500-2000m

.16

.365

Other

.00

.000

>2000m

.08

.279

Li

v

in

g

R

o

o

m

F

lo

o

r

Stone Tile

.07

.251

O

cc

u

p

an

cy

Vacant

.29

.453

Prefinished

Hardwood

.57

.497

Tenant

.33

.470

Unfinished

Hardwood

.27

.445

Owner

.39

.490

Ceramic

.04

.195

Laminate

.02

.129

F

ro

n

t

si

d

e

to

North

.17

.380

Carpet

.01

.106

South

.53

.501

Other

.03

.181

East

.24

.429

R

o

o

m F

lo

o

r

Stone Tile

.05

.220

West

.22

.415

Prefinished

Hardwood

.54

.500

Th

e

N

u

m

b

er

o

f

Dwellings (in

apt.)

11.51

8.009

Unfinished

Hardwood

.31

.463

Rooms

3.54

.648

Ceramic

.04

.195

Bathrooms

1.07

.251

Laminate

.02

.129

Balconies

1.93

.737

Carpet

.01

.106

Elevators

.28

.451

Other

.04

.195

Lo

ca

ti

o

n

Street

.60

.491

B

at

h

ro

o

m

F

lo

o

r

Stone Tile

.02

.129

Main Street

.39

.490

Glazed tile

.44

.498

Avenue

.03

.181

Ceramic

.54

.499

On the Corner

.48

.501

Other

.01

.075

Ground Survey

.53

.501

W

in

d

o

w

F

ra

mes

Wooden

.11

.317

Sunblind

.08

.270

Aluminum

.22

.419

Solar Water Heating

.28

.451

PVC

.66

.476

Located in-Site

.33

.470

Other

.01

.075

Garden

.61

.490

R

o

o

f

Betony

.06

.241

Ventilation

.70

.459

Clay Tile

.93

.251

Meter Square

119.97

24.772

Profiled Sheeting

.02

.129

Floor Level

2.63

1.339

W

al

l

Plastic Paint

.56

.498

Fire Exit

.20

.399

Oil Paint

.07

.251

Satellite TV

.27

.445

Satin Paint

.37

.483

Doorman

.37

.483

Wallpaper

.00

.000

Hydrophor Pump

.62

.486

(8)

This study estimates the hedonic price model through the E-Views

program. To find out the most suitable model, the study utilizes the most

commonly used top-to-down or general-to-specific approaches (Gujarati 1999)

of Hendry (1985) or the so-called London School of Economics (LSE)

Approach. The initial model covered all of the variables, and then the most

insignificant ones were removed from the model in order until a significance

level of

0

.

20

was achieved, with the following variables: heating by stove;

living room floor–stone tile; bathroom floor–stone tile; wooden window frames;

betony roof; walls–oil paint; house on the corner; house vacant; house with

front side to north; distance to city center-500–1000m. The variables that were

found to be significant and the related models are presented in Table 2. The

existence of heteroskedasticity in the models was tested via

Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey test and rejected at

0

.

05

.

Table 2: Results for the Linear, Logarithmic, and Log-linear Models

Variables Linear Model Log-linear Model Log-Log Model

Coefficient Significance Coefficient Significance Coefficient Significance Central Heating

(Apartment) 12.81457 0.0001 0.117066 0.0000 0.124027 0.0000 Living Room Floor:

unfinished hardwood 5.819712 0.1690 - - - -

Living Room Floor:

Ceramic - - -0.102628 0.0471 -0.093858 0.0638

Bathroom Floor Ceramic 5.101686 0.0498 0.051819 0.0133 0.042196 0.0439 On the Street 4.860699 0.0676 0.035469 0.1235 0.035097 0.1178 Satellite TV 6.782905 0.0538 0.070542 0.0133 0.048301 0.0790 Hidrophor Pump 5.275722 0.0741 0.053024 0.0239 0.054837 0.0184 Parking Lot 3.732982 0.2059 - - 0.029643 0.2226 Modular Kitchen 3.550859 0.1859 0.039558 0.0653 0.029484 0.1641 Sunblind 12.72444 0.0096 0.093856 0.0130 0.098895 0.0074

Solar Water Heating 4.272688 0.1716 0.032140 0.1912 0.039805 0.1019

In-Site -11.02580 0.0003 -0.080453 0.0007 -0.078754 0.0010

Garden - - -0.030564 0.1836 -0.037945 0.1168

Fire Exit - - -0.045414 0.1327 - -

Occupied by Tenant -5.529069 0.0951 - - - -

Occupied by Owner -5.081245 0.1115 - - - -

Front Side to South 5.327686 0.0500 0.044006 0.0422 0.038325 0.0724 Front Side to West -5.490518 0.0830 -0.044016 0.0823 -0.042196 0.0871

On the Corner -3.326854 0.1979 - - - -

Distance to City Centre:

1500-2000m 7.787394 0.0269 0.065401 0.0231 0.066403 0.0175

The Number of Bathrooms 14.86537 0.0054 0.063349 0.1352 0.082357 0.0462

The Number of Rooms -4.772347 0.0615 - - -0.106115 0.1115

Meter Square 0.721088 0.0000 0.005275 0.0000 0.691436 0.0000 The Number of Elevators 13.83910 0.0001 0.104916 0.0002 0.097921 0.0003 The Number of Dwellings

in the Building 0.234487 0.1363 0.002469 0.0482 - -

The Age of the Building - - -0.002554 0.1069 -0.016317 0.1736 F Value 28.86337 0.000000 34.92061 0.000000 36.63798 0.000000 R2/Adjusted R2 0.811703 0.783581 0.816463 0.793082 0.823548 0.801070

Ø 0.424913 6.270495 4.94169

2

(9)

5. INTERPRETATION AND SIGNIFICANCE OF THE COEFFICIENTS

Following are the findings from the hedonic model estimated for Mugla

Center:

 Central heating in the apartment, rather than a stove, increases the

hedonic price of the house 12.8 unit in the linear model, 11% in the

log-linear model, and 0.12% in the log-log model. Moreover, the coefficient

of the central heating is positive and significant at 1% in all the three

models.

 Ceramic tile floor in the bathroom, rather than stone tile, increases the

hedonic price of the house 5.1 unit in the linear model, 5% in the

log-linear model, and 0.04% in the log-log model. The coefficient of the

ceramic tile floor in the bathroom is positive and significant at 5% in all

the three models.

 Location on the street increases the hedonic price of the house 4.8 unit

in the linear model, 3% in the linear model, and 0.03% in the

log-log model. The coefficient of location on the street is positive in all the

three models but significant only in the linear model at 10%. In the

other models, this variable does not have any affect on the hedonic

price.

 Satellite TV increases the hedonic price of the house 6.78 unit in the

linear model, 7% in the log-linear model, and 0.04% in the log-log

model. The coefficient of satellite TV is positive in all the three models

and significant at 5% in the linear model and at 10% in the other

models.

 Hydrophor pump increases the hedonic price of the house 5.27 unit in

the linear model, 5% in the log-linear model, and 0.05% in the log-log

model. The coefficient of hydrophor pump is positive in all the three

models and significant at 10% in the linear model and at 5% in the

other models.

 Sunblind increases the hedonic price of the house 12.72 unit in the

linear model, 9% in the log-linear model, and 0.09% in the log-log

model. The coefficient of sunblind is positive in all the three models

and significant at 5% in the log-log model and at 1% in the other

models.

 The coefficient of location in a site is negative and significant at 1% in

all the three models. This variable decreases the hedonic price of the

house 11 unit in the linear model, 8% in the log-linear model, and

0.07% in the log-log model.

 Front side to south, rather than to north, increases the hedonic price of

the house 5.32 unit in the linear model, 4% in the log-linear model, and

0.03% in the log-log model. The coefficient of this variable is positive

(10)

in all the three models and significant at 10% in the linear and log-log

models and at 5% in the log-linear model.

 Front side to west, rather than to north, increases the hedonic price of

the house 5.49 unit in the linear model, 4% in the log-linear model, and

0.042% in the log-log model. The coefficient of this variable is negative

and significant at 10% in all the three models.

 A distance of 12000m to the city center, compared to that of

500-1000m, increases the hedonic price of the house 7.78 unit in the linear

model, 6% in the log-linear model, and 0.06% in the log-log model.

The coefficient of this variable is positive and significant at 5% in all

the three models.

 One-unit increase in the number of bathrooms increases the hedonic

price of the house 14.86 unit in the linear model, and 6% in the

log-linear model. On the other hand, 1% increase in the number of

bathrooms increases the hedonic price 0.08% in the log-log model. The

coefficient of this variable is positive in all the three models and

significant at 1% in the linear model and 5% in the log-log model,

while it is insignificant in the log-linear model.

 One-unit increase in the meter square of the house increases its hedonic

price 0.72 unit in the linear model, and 0.5% in the log-linear model.

On the other hand, 1% increase in the meter square of the house

increases its hedonic price 0.06% in the log-log model. The coefficient

of this variable is positive and significant at 1% in all the three models.

 One-unit increase in the number of elevators in the building increases

the hedonic price of the house 13.83 unit in the linear model, and 10%

in the log-linear model. On the other hand, 1% increase in the meter

square of the house increases its hedonic price 0.09% in the log-log

model. The coefficient of this variable is positive and significant at 1%

in all the three models.

F values regarding the findings above are significant at

0

.

01

level.

In addition,

R

2

values indicate that these variables explain approximately 81%

of the change in the hedonic price of the house.

6. CONCLUSION

The findings revealed by the econometric model in this study on

estimating hedonic price parameters in the real estate market in Mugla province

have met the theoretical and economic expectations. In other words, considering

the structure and features of Mugla, the estimated coefficients are found to be

significant in terms of both the characteristics of housing and its location (its

position, whether it is in-site or not, etc.).

(11)

As expected, the variables that positively affect the housing price have

been found in all linear, logarithmic, and log-linear models to be central

heating, ceramic bathroom floor, location on the street, satellite TV, hydrophor

pump, modular kitchen, sunblind, solar water heating, front side facing south,

1500-2000 meters to the city center, the number of bathrooms, square meter of

housing, and elevator.

The affect of particularly two variables on housing prices needs to be

interpreted taking into account the structure and characteristics of Mugla.

In-Site Location of Housing: The analysis has revealed by all the three

models that in-site location of housing negatively affect the price of housing,

implying that in-site location decreases the price of housing. The reason

underlying this argument may be that housing in Mugla is mostly in cooperative

type, and their prices are relatively lower, which is attributable to the common

opinion that the material and workmanship used in this kind of housing is of

low quality.

Distance to the City Center (1500–2000m): Our findings suggest that

the price of houses is higher if distance to the city center is 1500–2000 meters.

This is mainly because the closer areas, up to an approximate distance of 2 km,

are not allowed for construction in Mugla. That is why such a distance is

considered close to the city center, and in this manner housing tends to become

more expensive as it gets closer to such a distance.

This study has the merit of identifying the factors that may affect the

housing prices in Mugla at present and in the future by means of hedonic

models, providing a data set on the real estate market for both buyers and

sellers.

7. REFERENCES

Bartik, T. J. (1987). ―The Estimation of Demand Parameters in Hedonic Price

Models‖, The Journal Of Political Economy, 95(1): 81-88.

Blackley, D.M., J.R. Follain and H.Lee. (1986). ―An Evaluation of Hedonic

Price Indexes for Thirty Four Large SMSAs‖, AREUEA Journal, 14(2):

179-205.

Bover, O. and P.Velilla. (2002). ―Hedonic House Prices Without

Characteristics: The Case of New Multiunit Housing‖, European

Central Bank Working Paper Series, Working Paper No.117.

Can, A. and I. Megbolugbe. (1997). ―Spatial Dependence and House Price

Index Construction‖, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics,

14: 203–222.

Cohen, J. P. and C. C. Coughlin. (2006). ―Airport-Related Noise, Proximity,

and Housing Prices in Atlanta‖, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(12)

Colwell, P.F. and G. Dilmore. (1999). ―Who Was First? An Examination of an

Early Hedonic Study‖, Land Economics, 75(4): 620-626.

Court, A. T. (1939). Hedonic Price Indexes with Automotive Examples in

Dynamic of Automobile Demand, General Motors, New York.

Cowling, K. and J. Cubbin. (1972). ―Hedonic Price Indexes for United Kingdom

Cars‖, Economic Journal, 82 (September): 963-978.

Filho, C. M. and O. Bin. (2005). ―Estimation of Hedonic Price Functions via

Additive Nonparametric Regression‖, Empirical Economics, 30: 93–

114.

Goodman, A. C. (1978). ―Hedonic Prices, Price Indices, and Housing Markets‖,

Journal of Urban Economics, 5(4): 471-84.

Goodman, A. C. (1988). ―An Econometric Model of Housing Price, Permanent

Income, Tenure Choice, and Housing Demand‖, Journal of Urban

Economics, 23: 327-353.

Goodman, A. C. (1998). ―Andrew Court and the Invention of Hedonic Price

Analyzis‖, Journal of Urban Economics, 44(2): 291-298.

Gujarati, D.N. (1999). Temel Ekonometri, Çev:Ü.Şenesen ve G:G:Şenesen,

Literatür Yayıncılık, İstanbul.

Harsman, B. and J.M. Quigley. (1991). Housing Markets and Housing

Institutions: An International Comparison,. Kluwer Academic Press,

Boston.

Kain, J. F. and J. M. Quigley. (1970). ―Measuring the Value of Housing

Quality‖, Journal Of The American Statistical Association, 65 (330):

532-548.

Kaul, S. (2006). Hedonism and Culture: Impact on Shopper Behaviour, Indian

Institute of Management Publication.

Kim, S. (1992). ―Search, Hedonic Prices and Housing Demand‖,

The Review of

Economics and Statistics, 74(3) : 503-508.

Lancaster, K. J. (1966). ―A New Approach to Consumer Theory‖, Journal of

Political Economy, 74: 132-57.

Leishman, C. (2001). ―House Building and Product Differentiation: An Hedonic

Price Approach‖, Journal of Housing and the Built Environment, 16:

131–152.

Li, W., Prud‘Homme M. and Yu K. (2006). Studies in Hedonic Resale Housing

Price Indexe, OECD-IMF Workshop.

Macedo, R. (1996). ―Hedonic Price Models with Spatial Effects: An

Application to the Housing Market of Belo Horizonte, Brazil‖, Revista

(13)

Maurer, R., M. Pitzer and S. Sebastian. (2004). ―Hedonic Price Indices for the

Paris Housing Market‖, Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv, 88: 303-326.

Meese, R. and N. Wallace. (1991). ―Nonparametric Estimation of Dynamic

Hedonic Price Models and the Constructions of Residential Housing

Price Indices‖, AREUEA Journal, 19(3):308-332.

Meese, R. and N. Wallace. (1997). "The Construction of Residential Housing

Price Indices: A Comparison of Repeat-Sales, Hedonic-Regression, and

Hybrid Approaches", Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics,

14: 51–73.

Mendelsohn, R. (1984). ―Estimating the Structural Equations of Implicit

Markets and Household Production Functions‖, The Review of

Economics and Statistics, 66(4): 673-677.

Ogwang, T. and B. Wang. (2002). ―A Hedonic Price Function for a Northern

BC Community‖, Social Indicators Research, 61: 285-296.

Palmquist, R. B. (1984). ―Estimating the Demand for the Characteristics of

Housing‖, Review of Economics and Statistics, 66(3): 394-404.

Powe, N.A., Garrod G.D., Brunsdon C.F. and K.G. Willis. (1997). ―Using a

Geographic Information System to Estimate a Hedonic Price Model of

the Benefits of Woodland Access‖, Forestry, 70(21): 39-149.

Ramanathan, R. (1998). Introductory Econometrics with Applications, The

Dryden Press, Fourth Edition.

Ridker, R.G. and J.A. Henning. (1967). ―The Determinants of Residential

Property Values with Special Reference to Air Pollution‖ The Review of

Economics and Statistics, 49: 246–257.

Rosen, S. (1974). ―Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product

Differentiation in Pure Competition‖, Journal of Political Economy, 82:

34-55.

Straszheim, M.R. (1973). ―Estimation Of The Demand For Urban Housing

Services From Household Interview Data‖, Review of Economics and

Statistics, 55: 1-8.

Straszheim, M.R. (1974). ―Hedonic Estimation of Housing Market Prices: A

Further Comment‖, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 56(3):

404-406.

Toda, Y. and N. N. Nozdrina. (2004). ―The Spatial Distribution of the

Apartment Prices In Moscow in 2002: Hedonic Estimation from Micro

Data‖ ENHR Conference July 2nd-6th 2004, Cambridge.

Üçdoğruk, Ş. (2001). ―İzmir İlinde Emlak Fiyatlarına Etki Eden Faktörler:

Hedonik Yaklaşım‖, D.E.Ü. İ.İ.B.F. Dergisi, 16(2): 149-161.

Wallace, H.A. (1926). ―Comparative Farmland Values in Iowa‖, Journal of

(14)

Wen H., J. Sheng-Hua and G. Xiao-Yu. (2005). ―Hedonic Price Analysis of

Urban Housing: An Empirical Research on Hangzhou, China‖, Journal

of Zhejiang University Science, 6A (8):907-914.

Wen, H.Z., J.F. Lu, and L. Lin. (2004). An Improved Method of Real Estate

Evaluation Based on Hedonic Price Model, International Management

Conference.

Wilhelmsson, M. (2002). ―Household Expenditure Patterns for Housing

Attributes: A Linear Expenditure System with Hedonic Prices‖, Journal

of Housing Economics, 11: 75–93.

Witte, A. D., H. Sumka and J. Erekson. (1979). ―An Estimate of a Structural

Hedonic Price Model of the Housing Market: An Application of

Rosen's Theory of Implicit Markets‖, Econometrica, 47: 1151-72.

Yang, Z. (2000). ―An Application of the Hedonic Price Model with Uncertain

Attribute: The Case of the People's Republic of China‖, Property

Management, 19(1): 50-63.

Yankaya, U. ve M. Çelik. (20059. ―İzmir Metrosunun Konut Fiyatları

Üzerindeki Etkilerinin Hedonik Fiyat Yöntemi İle Modellenmesi‖,

(15)

Appendix: Examples of Hedonic Pricing Models in House Markets

Study,

Data and

Functional

Form

Variables

Conclusions and Evaluation

Ridker & Henning (1967) , 167 Observation About House Selling, Linear Functional Form

Dependent Variable: Median value

of owner-occupied single family housing units

Independent Variables:

(1) An index of annual geometric mean sulfation levels, (2) Median number of rooms per housing unit, (3) Percentage recently built, (4) Total houses per square mile of tracts, (5) Time zone for central business district, (6) Percentage non-white housing units, (7) School quality, (8) Occupation ratio, (9) Highway accessibility, (10) İllionis/ Missouri dummy variable, (11) Persons per unit, (12) Median family income, (13) Index of annual geometric mean concentrations of suspended particulates gathered by high-volume air samplers, (14) Percentage substandart, (15) Crime rate, (16) Shopping area accessibility, (17) Industrial area accessibility, (18) Social area analysis indexes.

—This study was one of the earliest to apply hedonic price theory for analyze the housing market and calculated the impact of improving environmental quality on housing price.

—The variables which causes multicollinearity problem also featured in the study and introduced the results if including these varibles or not. Thus, adjustments for multicollinearity choosing four different estimating method.

—The most important results are statistically significant and all are fairly reasonable within the context of the area. —Sulfation levels to which any single-family dwelling unit is exposed were to drop by 0.25 mg./100cm2/day, the value of that property could be expected to rise by at least $83 and more likely closer to $245.23.

—Characteristics specific to the property [variable (2),(3) and (4)] all turned out to be important explanatory variables. The sign and magnitudes of their coefficients are as expected.

— Both variables (5) and (9) are statistically significant. The coefficients attached to variable (5) , however, are not quite as expected.

—Variable (8) proved to be best estimated among neighbourhood characteristics. The coefficients of variable (7) are positive. Kain & Quigley (1970) , 1184 Observation In The Entire Model And 854 Observation For The Restricted Model About House Selling,,Semi-Logarithmic and Linear Functional Forms

Dependent Variable: Dwelling unit

price

Independent Variables:

(1) Basic residential quality, (2) Dwelling unit quality, (3) Quality of proximate properties, (4) Nonresidential usage, (5) Avarage structure quality, (6) Proportion white in census tract, (7) Median schooling of adults in census tract, (8) Public School achievement, (9) Number of major crimes, (10) Age of structure, (11) Number of rooms (natural log.), (12) Number of bathrooms, (13) Parcel area (hundreds of sq. ft.), (14) First flor area (hundreds of sq. ft.), (15) Single detached, (16) Duplex, (17) Row, (18) Apartment, (19) Rooming house, (20) Flat, (21) No heat included in rent, (22) No water included in rent, (23) No major appliances included in rent, (24) No furniture included in rent, (25) Hot water, (26) Central heat, (27) Duration of occupancy (years), (28) Owner in building

—This article estimates the market value, or the implicit prices of specific aspects of the bundles of residential services consumed by urban households. Quantitative estimates were obtained by regressing market price of owner-and renter-occupied dwelling units on measures of the qualitative and quantitative dimensions of the housing bundles.

—The measures of residential quality obtained by using factor analysis to aggregate some 39 indexes of the quality. —For renters equations used 25 variable and for owners equations used 15 variable in the study.

—The analysis indicates that the quality of the bundles of residential services has about as much effect on the price of housing as such objective aspects as the number of rooms, number of bathrooms, and lot size.

—For renters, among the first 5 quality variables, variable (1), (2) and (5) are statistically significiant in the model which have restristed observation. For owners, among the first 5 quality variables, variable (3) and (5) are not statistically significiant in the model which have restristed observation. For renters equations only 16 variable and for owners equations only 5 variable are statistically significiant at %5 significance level.

—The most striking difference when the model is reestimated for the entire obvervations is the increase in the significance of the coefficients.

(16)

Study,

Data and

Functional Form

Variables

Conclusions and Evaluation

Straszheim (1973), Household Interview Data For 1965 (100-200 Observation About House Selling), Linear Functional Form

Dependent Variable: Price of

standartized dwelling unit

Independent Variables:

(1) Probability of ownership, (2) Number of rooms in dwelling units, (3) Structure age dummies, (4) Lot size dummies, (5) Structure condition dummies, (6) Unsound condition dummies, (7) Sample size

—Separate equations were estimated for owner and rental units, and for each geographic submarket.

—It was found strong relationship between house price and variables (3), (4) and (7).

— Variables (3) and (4) were always statistically significiant.

—Analysis of covariance tests reveal satatistically significiant differences in the equations across zones.

—There is substantial spatial variation in the price of most attributes of housing services.

Straszheim (1974), Pooled Data Of The 3 Different District About House Characteristics, Linear Functional Form

Dependent Variable: House

selling price

Independent Variables:

(1) Number of rooms, (2) Built in pre1940, (3) Built in 1940–1945, (4) Built in 1950–1959, (5) Lot size less than 2 acre, (6) Lot size between 3–5 acre, (7) Lot size greater than 5 acre, (8) Unsound condition dummy , (9) Sample size

—F-tests reveal that the geographic stratification reduces the residual sum of squared errors. A few of the individual submarket equations are presented to illustrate the range of estimates obtained.

—Though suburban submarkets exhibit more price homogeneity, there are also limits to how wide a geographic area can be employed.

—The discussion of hedonic price estimation might more usefully be directed to the criteria which should be employed to define homogenous submarkets within urban areas. Goodman (1978), 1835 Observation About House Selling, Box-Cox Functional Form

Dependent Variable: House

selling price

Independent Variables:

(1) Lot size in sq. ft., (2) 1 if house is all brick; 0 otherwise, (3) 1 if hardwood floors; o otherwise, (4) Number of covered garage spaces, (5) Age of house in years, (6) Number of rooms excluding bathrooms, lavatories, (7) Number of full bathrooms, (8) Number of Lavatories, (9) Indoor living space in sq. Ft., (10) Number of fireplaces, (11) Percentage balack population, (12) Percentage families with income less than 5000 $, (13) Percentage of population over age 25 with 13 or more years of education, (14) 1 if black is greater than %5 and less than %15, (15) Principle components measure of neighbourhood attitudes

— This study appears to clarify several aspects of housing analysis using hedonic prices, with respect to market segmentation, functional form and behavior of prices within submarkets. In positing various spatially and temporally separate submarkets, covariance analysis indicates heterogeneity of coefficients.

-—Model results showed that, Variables affect the house prices differently in urban and suburb areas and for both structure and neighbourhood characteristics the price are up to 20% higher than the suburbs.

— Intrametropolitan examination of structural and neighborhood quality reveals that the relative valuation of physical improvements in housing is smaller in the central city than in the suburbs, while the relative valuation of improved neighborhoods is relatively constant.

-— Aggregation of hedonic price coefficients into standardized units yields significantly higher housing prices in the central city than in its suburbs, as well as differential effects of structural and neighborhood improvements among submarkets.

(17)

Study,

Data and

Functional

Form

Variables

Conclusions and

Evaluation

Witte & Sumka & Erekson (1979), 500 Observation About House Rents In Four City, Linear Functional Form

Dependent Variable: House rent

Independent Variable (For Consumers): (1) Total annual current

income of household, (2) Age in years of the head of household, (3) 1 If the head of household is employed in blue collar job; 0 otherwise, (4) 1 If the head of household is employed in white collar job; 0 otherwise, (5) 1 if the highest level of education attained by head of household is high school; 0 otherwise, (6) 1 if the head of household has education beyond the high school level; 0 otherwise, (7) The number of persons in the household, (8) 1 if the household head is female and 0 if male.

Independent Variable (For Supplier): (1) The number of years the landlord has owned the dwelling, (2) 1 if there is a lease; 0 otherwise, (3) 1 if the family has lived in the dwelling for five years or more; 0 otherwise, (4) 1 if the landlord is resident in the dwelling; 0 otherwise, (5) 1 if rent is collected more often than once a month; 0 otherwise, (6) 1 if a professional manager is employed; 0 otherwise, (7) The number of rental units owned, (8) 1 if ownership is of the corporate form; 0 otherwise, (9) 1 if the rental housing owned was acquired by inheritance; 0 otherwise, (10) 1 if the head of household is black; 0 otherwise.

Other Independent Variables: (1) Dwelling quality, (2) Dwelling

size, (3) Lot size, (4) Neighbourhood quality, (5) A measure of accessibility

—In this study, estimated a simultaneous system of hedonic price equations suggested by the work of Rosen. This system consisted of bid and offer curves for each of housing bundle attributes, dwelling quality, dwelling size, and lot size.

—Empirical results confirm the theoretically expected negative coefficient for each attribute in its own bid price equation and the expected positive or zero coefficient for each attribute in its own offer function.

—An examination of cross price relationships among the attributes revealed an intriguing and generally logical pattern of interactions both on the demand and the supply sides.

Palmquist (1984), .20297 Observation About House Selling, Linear, Semi-Logarithmic, Log-Linear and Inverse Semi-Logarithmic Functional Forms

Dependent Variable: House selling price

Independent Variables:(1) Area of lot in sq. ft., (2) Finished interior

area in sq. ft., (3) Finished interior area squared, (4) Number of bathrooms, (5) Year of construction, (6) Number of stalls in garage, (7) Number of stalls in carport, (8) 1 if garage is detached from house, (9) 1 if there is underground wiring, (10) 1 if there is a dishwasher, (11) 1 if there is a garbage disposal, (12) 1 if there is central air conditioning, (13) 1 if there is wall air conditioning units, (14) 1 if there is a ceiling fan, (15) 1 if the date of sale was 1976, (16) Excellent condition, (17) Fair condition, (18) Poor condition, (19) Brick or stone exterior finish, (20) 1 if there is a full basement, (21) 1 if there is a partial besement, (22) 1 if there are one or more fireplaces, (23) 1 if there is a swimming pool, (24) The annual arithmetic mean of the particulate air pollution level, (25) The median age of the residents of the census tract, (26) The median family income of residents of the census tract, (27) The percentage of workers in the census tract that has a blue collar job, (28) The percentage of houses in the census tract that has changed ownership within the last five years, (29) The percentage of the population of the census tract that is classified as non-white, (30) The percentage of the population of the census tract over 24 years old that has graduated from high school, (31) The percentage of the structures in the census tract with 1.00 or less persons per room, (32) The number of work destinations within the census tract divided by the area of the census tract, (33) Adjusted monthly housing expenditure, (34) Hedonic price of sq. ft. of living space, (35) Hedonic price of bathrooms, (36) Hedonic price of the percentage of the census tract with high school degrees, (37) Hedonic price of racial homogeneity, (38) Hedonic price of lot area, (39) Hedonic price of reduction in age of house, (40) Age of the purchaser, (41) 1 if the purchaser is single, (42) Number of dependents in the family making the purchase, (43) 1 if the purchaser is black.

—First, linear hedonic regression equations were constructed and in the second srtage estimated logarithmic linear estimates for house characteristics in the study. To reduce the costs of estimation, the search was restricted to the four functional forms most frequently used: linear, semi-logarithmic, log-linear and ınverse semi-logarithmic.

—With approximately 200 coefficients estimated, there are only 17 with incorrect signs and none of these are for the most important variables. Hedonic regression results showed that variables (3), (8), (18), (24), (28) and (29) affects house prices negatively. First 32 variables except variables (3), (8), (18), (24), (28) and (29) affects house prices positively and the variables which were positively affects house prices have expected signs and magnitudes, also they were statistically significiant. In the second stage, variables (33), (34) (42) and (43) were more effective on the house prices and these variables which were statistically significiant have positive coefficients.

(18)

Study,

Data and

Functional

Form

Variables

Conclusions and Evaluation

Goodman (1988), 2857 Observation About House Selling, Box-Cox Functional Form

Dependent Variable: House selling price Independent Variables: (1) 1 if central air, o

otherwise, (2) 1 if heating breakdowns in past 90 days, 0 otherwise, (3) Number of full bathrooms, (4) Number of bedrooms, (5) Number of utility breakdowns in past 90 days, (6) Age of house in year, (7) 1 if full cellar, 0 otherwise, (8) 1 if electricity used for cooking, 0 otherwise, (9) 1 if open holes or cracks, 0 otherwise, (10) 1 if additional heating equipment used, 0 otherwise , (11) 1 if Steam heat, 0 otherwise, (12) 1 if gas heat, 0 otherwise, (13) Rating neighborhood, 1 (best)…,4 (worst), (14) 1 if fuses blown in past 90 days, 0 otherwise, (15) Number of lavatories, (16) Years residing in dwelling unit, (17) Number of rooms without hot air ducts, (18) 1 if plaster broken over 1 foot 2 , 0 otherwise, (19) 1

if Access to other rooms through bedroom, 0 otherwise, (20) 1 if sign of rats ın past 90 days, 0 otherwise, (21) Number of rooms, (22) Logarithm of property tax rate, (23) Garage/carport available for use, (24) Location dummies, (25) City dummies, (26) 1 if passenger elevator in building, 0 otherwise, (27) Number of extra features included in rent, (27) Number of stories in building, (28) 1 if heat included in rent, 0 otherwise, (29) 1 if Single family Structure, 0 otherwise.

—Hedonic price methods define price indices for owner and renter housing and define value-rent ratios for the investment components of the housing purchase. Permanent income is estimated for both owners and renters. Tenure choice is estimated using the price, value-rent ratios, permanent and transitory incomes, and sociodemographic variables. Housing demand is estimated for both owners and renters.

—The adjusted R2 is 0.6025 for the value

regressions, as opposed to 0.4585 for the rent regressions. Abathroom adds 26 % to the house value and 28.5 % to the apartment rent. An additional room adds 7.3 % to the value and 6.0 % to the rent. An owner (renter) unit loses About 0.53 % (0.28 %) of value (rent) per year.

— Neighborhood effects are considerably weaker for renter units. A unit improvement in the quality of neighborhood Structure leads to a 3.8 % rent increase; for owner housing the percentage increase is 7.5 %.

—There is significant regional variation in owner housing prices, there is less variation in quality-adjusted rents.

—Variables (2), (5), (13), (16), (17), (19) and (22) were affects house value and rents negatively.

Meese & Wallace (1991), Time Series Data For 2 Different City For The Years Between 1970–1988, Trans-Log and Log-Linear Functional Form

Dependent Variable: House selling price

Independent Variables:

(1) Number of bathrooms, (2) Sq. Ft. Of floor space (m2), (3) Number of total rooms, (4) Index

of house condition, (5) Federal mortgage, (6) Multiple sales dummy variable, (7) Mortgage assumability dummy, (8) Residential zoning dummy, (9) Swimming pool dummy, (10) Fireplace dummy, (11) Age of dwelling (years).

—In this paper advocating the use of nonparametric regression techniques to construct housing price indices.

—The analysis includes an examination of the variation in the implicit price of house attributes over time, diagnostic checks of the adequacy of the fitted hedonics, and simulated confidence intervals for the Fisher Ideal Price index.

—For Diedmont city variables (6) and (11) have positive and negative coefficients respectively. Variables (1), (2), (3), (4), (7), (9) and (10) have positive signs and have positive effects on the house selling prices. Moreover, variable (5) states less expensive houses and have negative signs. —For San Francisco city only variable (5), (7) and (8) have negative signs.

(19)

Study,

Functional

Form, Data

Variables

Conclusions and Evaluation

Can & Megbolugbe (1997), 944 Observation About House Selling, Linear Functional Form

Dependent Variable: House selling

price

(1) Living area in sq. ft., (2) Land area in sq. ft., (3) Age of the structure, (4) Composite neighborhood quality score

Neighborhood quality variables:

—Owner-occupancy rate —Median household income —Percentage of residents with college education

—Percentage of households paying at least 30 % of income on monthly housing costs —Median value of owner-occupied housing

—Vacancy rate

—Median age of housing stock —Percentage of detached signle-family units

—Percentage of white-headed, balack-headed and hispanic-balack-headed

—Study illustrates the importance of spatial dependence in both the specification and estimation of hedonic price models. In this article, presenting the importance of spatial dependence on the specification of a house price function due to the presence of spatial spillover effects in the operation of local housing markets. With the spatial models which constructed in the article, it would be possible to adjust the confidence intervals of the metropolitan –level indices to reflact the localized dependencies in the house price determination process. —Models also achieve very reasonable estimates of marginal prices for selected attributes. Spatial dependence plays an important role in the house price determination process.

— Variable (2) is not statistically significant in both 6 regression equations of study. Except variable (2), other variables have a hidh significance levels and have different effects on the house selling prices.

—This study rpresents an attempt to derive useful house price indices from large data sets containing only alimited number of variables.

- —The R2 value in the spatial hedonic expansion models

which have strong consequences was more than spatial hedonic and traditional hedonic models.

Meese & Wallace (1997), 27606 Observation About House Selling In Two District Over An 18 Years Period, Translog and Log-Linear Functional Forms

Dependent Variable: House selling price

Independent Variables:

(1) Number of bathrooms, (2) Number of bedrooms, (3) Sq. ft. of lot size, (4) Number of rooms, (5) House quality index, (6) Age of structure.

—This article examines a number of hypotheses that underpin the repeat-sales and hedonic approaches to the construction of housing price indices, as well as the practical problems associated with the implementation od either approach.

—Study examines a hybrid procedure that combines elements of both the repeat-sales and hedonic regression techniques.

—In this article, documenting the shortcomings of repeat-sales price indices when they are constructed on municipality-level data sets. The indices suffer from sample selection bias and nonconstancy of implicit housing characteristic prices, and the yare quite sensitive to small sample problems.

—The standart variance specification of repeat-sales approaches appears to be inappropriate for data at the municipality level.

—Repeat sales methods reject the assumption that changing attribute prices over time.

Referanslar

Benzer Belgeler

The system uses naive Bayes classifiers to learn models for region segmentation and classification from automatic fusion of features, fuzzy modeling of region spatial relationships

Abdî, Abdal, Agahî, Ahî, Ali, Arabî, Arifoğlu, Âşık Ali, Âşık Hasan, Âşık Muhammed, Âşık, Bahrî, Bayadî Veysî, Bedirî, Boranî, Cemalî, Cevabî,

Sonuçta Yüce Divan’m 3 Kasım 1929 tarihli oturumunda Mahmut Muhtar Paşa gerekli teminat mektubunun alınmamasından dolayı sorumlu görüle­ rek 20 bin lirayı

İlk tahsile Süleymaniyedeki Kaptanpaşa mektebinde başlamış ve orta tahsilinden sonra Kuleli askerî tıbbiye idadîsiie askerî rüşdiyeyi ik­ mal ederek

Memleketimizin dikkate lâyık elmalarından Celâl Y aln ız’ın (Sa­ kallı Celâl) çarşamba günü ânl bir kriz neticesinde vefat ettiğini derin bir teessürle

Bu çalışmada; öncelikle “dijital miras” konusu ele alınarak söz ko- nusu kavramın anlamı ve içeriği değerlendirilecek, akabinde sosyal medya (somut olay

Evlilik birliği içinde edinilmiş mallardaki artık değerin yarısına te- kabül eden katkı payı alacağının TMK’da tarif edilen hesap yöntemine göre, ölüm ya da boşanma

Through this account, financial support for plans, projects, implementation and expropriation are offered. The use of this fund is supervised by the governor. Grants offered