• Sonuç bulunamadı

The contradictions of development: primitive accumulation and geopolitics in the two Sudans

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The contradictions of development: primitive accumulation and geopolitics in the two Sudans"

Copied!
14
0
0

Yükleniyor.... (view fulltext now)

Tam metin

(1)

The contradictions of development

Primitive accumulation and geopolitics

in the two Sudans

1

Clemens Hoffmann

1 Introduction

0he recent opening ceremooy of the so-called:°C;;n;t; .. ,�;>rt and Lanw Southern Sudan-Ethiopia Transport Corridor (LAPSSET) has laid b;ue yet again ·the inherently-cc,;1tradTci:01y nature of pose-colonial devclop111em. The mega project creates a new East African transport corridor connecting land-locked South Sudan and Ethiopia with a 32-berth deep-sea water facility at the Indian ( kea;1. Among a variety of development objectives in the participatiog countries, the

_

__.

project is -designed to offer :in alternative export route for South Sudanese crude oil. Since its indepcndencc.'"tiic-.-;�;i�l's n�;es� .. c;;u;1-t;.y• ha�· b���� ;;�--l�ggerheads ·widi' its forn1c,: rule� in 1<T1artou111 over a transfer fee tor using the pipeline, refineries and port facilities for the tradi­ tioml export route through the Red Sea.

'!

et even though the project, if in1ple111ented, will fiave a trenwndously positive effect on South Sudan\ devclopnient potenti:11, local communities in Lnnu daim they have not been consulted over the development of the UNESCO heritage site into a 111:tjor infrastructure hub (Cari 2012; York 2012).

This dispute rdkct� but one of the imminent contmdictions South Sudan faces in its effort to catch up. Closer to home, Foreign I )irect Investment (FDI) is sought to develop the post-war economy and incrcasc state revenue (S11dm1 Tri/11111t· 2012a) as well as agricultural production as a means to boost food security (Lupai 2012). This stratq,,y is influential across Africa (Bush et 11/. 201 l: 188 -9), but the Hom of Africa appear.; to be a special case due to its high vulnerability to food insecurity (USA 11) and Famine Early Waming System Network 2012). In fact, the UN World Food Progr.mime (Wf-P) expects to feed up to half of South Sudan's populati<rn in 2012 (WFP and FAO 2012). Mca.wred by these objectives, the land investment activity in South Smfan to this day has not yielded great resulr;,:---Acquisitions lacked good practice with regards to comn1unity consultatio1i and environmental · i·1i1pact assessments (Deng 20 I I), while most transactions appe:1r to remain merely speculative (Mosley 2012). It is not only food inscclllity that remains a paramount issue for the Republic of South Sudan, however, but also the long-established need to diver.;ify the �·conomy afi:er the dispute with the North has led to the loss of all oil revenues at a �e when 'internal' and 'external' contlicts spiral and put heavy burdens on the stretched budg/

(2)

In many w;1ys, however, che concradicciou between cou1munity rights and agricultural development, geared co increase production, either co meet local den1and or to increase state revenue as an export commodity, is not unique to South Sudan in 2012. Sudanese history fcawres a wealth of examples where concradictions turned into confrontation and anned struggle. Prior to che discovery of oil, the cot111try's couHicc-ridden trajectory from traditional modes of sub­ sistence co a modern capitalist regime of accun1ulation has by ;md large evolved 'on che ground' around transfon11ing land and labour into productive sources of surplus value, thought to fill imaginary African and Arab breadbaskets respectively. M:my contliccs and n1aybe even che division itself can be seen as a long-ten11 result of this process of 'mal-incegr.1cion' inco the capitalist world economy (Ayers 2010). Despite the new South Sudanese Land Act and Land Policy explicitly addressing sornc historic conflict dynamics around land by inscribing John Carang's slogan of 'l:md belonging co the people', so111e intrinsic contradictions should be on Juba 's radar. This chapter will provide an overview of historical and contemporary dynamics and tra11S­ fonnations leading to these development contradictions. The core subject matter of this analysis is che process of appropriation :111d primitive accrnnulation of previously t111conm1oditised productive resources, notably land, labour, capital and, in the case of agriculwral development, water. However, instead of merely identifying 'dispossessed' classes and 'appropriating' agents whose actions (or inactions) arc assumed to be mlely based on a self-interested pmfic motive, this chapter will further explore the co111plex set of global structural relations infor111i11g local agents and underlying their actions. While the literature has usefully rcfkcted 011 tm11s1wtior1c1/ global markets as a driving force behind such processes, notably in the form of foreign capital, somctilllcs competing strategic orientations of different state powers - in other words, geopolitiw/ relations and the ways in which they intenninglc with market relations - have received less attencion in the analysis. This chapter will try to remedy this shortcoming in the Sudanc.:se context. This c111ph;1sis on the dualistic structure of world µolitics comisting of global markets and an inter­ state system should not be read, however, as an attempt to diminish local, individual agency in the process, or as reducing them to passive executors of global or geopolitical imperatives. Equally. it is not intended to sec ;my of these spheres of social interaction as self-contained and unrelated to one another. Rather, this chapter aims to take into account regionnlly and his­ torically specific social relations between macro-structures and local agents and, in doing so, provides a nuanced analysis of che process of accun1ulation in Sudan and South Sudan.

2 Primitive accumulation, development and the state

2.1 The concept of primitive accumulation

Although the concept of 'previous accunn1lation' was first developed by Adam Smith (1982), it gained more prominence in Karl Marx's historical materialist re-conceptualisation as the process of 'prilllitive acclmwlation'. This is for Marx the historical proccs.� whereby producers arc divorced from their 111cans of production, notably the enclosure of land in 16th-century Eng­ land (Marx I 981: Ch. 2<>). This ace of dispossession of subsisre11<;e fanners from their pri111ary means of production is, however, not seen as a 'natmal' oc<.:urrcll(:c, but as :l precondition, instituted by extra-economic - i.e. political and violent - means, so that 111:irket relations can engage in a proces.� of illlpersonal, market-based appropriation lacer (Brenner 1985; Wood 1999). It involves not only the con11110dificatio11 of land vi;1 enclosing co111111<H1s, but also the transformation of peasants into waged agricultural labourers. The essential objective of this process is the commodification not only of land but of all factors of production, turning land, capital and labour imo marketable goods, gcnc1�1ting the specific form of soci:11 reproduction

(3)

known as capitalism. Marx's own preoccupation was with the transfon11:1tio11 of subsistence producers into wage labour, or the proletarianisation as the essential intermediary step in generat­ ing the fim1re revolutionary class. In that semc, he was not morally averse to the process, and in fact saw it as part of a necessary, if violent, transfom1ation. However, far from being a fin ice process whereby productive factors, once co1nmodified, remain in the market sphere, primitive accu­ mulation has to be understood more as a pennancm, infinite process necessitated by capitalism's expansion, and che need to overcome its inherent contradictions and co maintain the separation of producers from productive factors (De Angdis 2004; Luxemburg .1951 ). Even though Marx specifically refers to colonialism as one outc:0111<.: of this process, expansion docs not necessarily have to be seen as a territorial process only, but can involve constam transformations, in parti­ cular with regards to the changing nature of labour-capital relations within the 'global north', 'norch-somh' relations as well as incomplete transitions within the 'global south' (Harvey 2003). Civen the Marxist leanings of many Third World nationalise revolutionary movements, including the Sudan People Liberation Movemenc (SPLM) during che initial phases of the stniggle in 1983 (Berhanu 201 I: 83), 2 this concept has also found inroads into the development literature (Amin 1977). However, the major shortcoming in applying this concept to South Sudan is its presumption of :1 direct, stationary relation between producer and land. Disposses­ sion in the transition from fcud:1lis111 to capitalism in Europe thus required the extraction of direct producers from the land. In the case of more mobile fonns of subsistence, like pastoralism or shifting cultivation, the opposite transformation is required (and pursued): namely, the set­ tling of populations is a precondition for the commodification of land and labour. 'Primitive accumulation' in Africa is, thus, not always comparable to the processes in Europe. Apart from settling mobile populations, it also implies the monopolisation of land use and the dispossession of producers from their means of social reproduction. The role of states in general and post­ coloniaJ states in particular, rather than private entrepreneurship, is crucial in driving this socio­ economic transfonnation. In other words, coloni,11 administrations as well as post-colonial state formations introduce capitalist socinl relations. Though they never introduce an ideal-typical European 'mirror' image, transfonmtion always happens via a process of violent dispossession, rather than developing organically driven purely by an indigenous entrepreneurial spirit.3 This also includes the recognition that government accumulation can still be carried out with the objective of commoditisation, even if no privately owned capital is initially involved. Private ownership docs not per sc constitute a condition for co111n1oditisation, as the state is frequently the appropriator par excellence in post-colonial contexts - itself appropriated by private interest, local, national, global or simply intangible. Hence, different geographical instances of accu111ula­ cio11 and dispossession :ire hctcrogc.:ncous while historical and contemporary dynamics arc highly complex based on diffc.:n:m social formations producing different forms of resistance (Glassman 2006: (i22). In sum, the core premises of this analysis are that (a) accumulation and dispossession arc ;1 priori extra-economic, p<llitic<1/ processes, and (b) that they arc necessarily pem11111c11t in scope due the enduring labour-capital dialectic.

2.2 Primitive accumulation in the two Sudans

2.2.1 Sudan

A brief look at Sudan's histo1y reveals many instances of appropriation and dispossession, both in its colonial as well as its post-colonial histmy (e.g. Abdclkarim 1992; Ayers 20 I 0). Here, the

most frequently cited examples are the Gezir.1 and Gcdaref irrigated agricultural schemes, which

(4)

che local merchant (or circulation) capital. I kspite being institutionalised by the colonial masters and being run by private operators, che Sudanese state in its ditferent articulations remained the key agent of development as all land remained de jure public property (Bametc and Abdclkarint 1991). Sociologically, however, what Ayers calls Sudan's 'lllal-integration' into the global poli­ tical economy produced 'a dependent class of "local resource extractors'" (Ayers 2010: I 63), a loc"al appropriating capitalist class, who intensified resource extraction in Sudan in accordance with a global regime of growth and accumulation. On the Aipside, they served not only co deplete Sudan's ecolob'Y, but also to impoverish the vast majority of Sudan's population by making them low-income wage earners.

Primitive accumulation in Sudan arguably has a long tradition, though this history is rather complex and uneven. During the Turco-Egyptian and Anglo-Egyptian regimes, forms of pri­ vate landownership were established, while private 'foreign' capital (Greek and Syrian) had started penetrating Sudanese agriculture and semi-feudal landlords were established. These were usually dose to political power both prior to and after independence. This also implied ince­ wating into a global economy, appropriating land, labour and subsequently surpluses together with European formal or infonnal colonisers. This was particularly visible in the export-oriented cotton production in Chezira. In fact, cotton exports lllade for a trade surplus in the first years of the nowadays debt-stricken independent Sudan. As a result, it was the only post-colonial Arab state not declaring a large-sc:ile land refonu with independence (Awad 1971: 212), simply because it didn't appear necessary to the established beneficiaries of a system of global wealth extraction. In mher words, private and semi-statal forms of land au1t1isitio11s, but also the vio­ lent appropriation of free and unfree labour, had already developed as a 'tradition' in colonial and further into post-colonial Sudan. However, its uneven and partial nature had equally allowed pre-capitalist for111s of subsistence, in particular nomadic livelihoods, to survive.

The cmcial turning point in trying to close these gaps was President Ni111ery's 1970 Unre­ gistered Land Act, declaring all unclaimed land (i.e. unless claimed by investors) state property. This modern-day fonn of enclosure established the legal basis for large-sc:ale land acquisitions by Nimery's socialist-labelled regime. While it was by no nieans the first such exantplc, ic certainly constitutes a highlight in the uneven development of land -policy in pose-colonial Sudan. Modernisation and land reform came packaged in an agenda of 'Sudan ism' which was meant to overcome traditional, or rather fractional, rule. Nimery's administrative refonns reph1cing the 13ritish system of 'Native Administration' were meant to implement a more cemralised admin­ istration further facilitating land use. In reality, it represented only another step in the incom.! · plete transition from traditional to modern authority (cf Mamdani 2009: 173), creating what Mamdani calls many Sudans within a single state (ibid.: 174).

These were necessary steps to implement the 'Arab Bre:1dbasket' strategy, geared to supply food to the Middle East while raising national income through crops exports. It rested on three pillars, namely Sudanese land and resources, Arab capital and Westcm know-how. The 'know-how' came from Washinbrton as early as 1968, when. the Med1:1nised Fam1ing Corporation (MFC) was established upon request from the World Bank to secure loans and facilitate credit to famters (Sulin1an 1994: 16). Subsequent expansion of mechanjsed fanning was further fi.mded by the World Bank under the MFC umbrella. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) structural alljustment programmes continued the encouragement of brrowing export-oriented cash crops rather than establishing food security at home. This resulted in the slow loss of self-sufficiency for Sudan, once running a trade surplus, and applied not least to the cultivation of wheat, which was considered unsui­ table for an export-led growth regime by agricultural specialists. The Arab/ African food basket idcoloh'Y, in conjunction with the influx of foreign capital politically facilitated by the Washington Consensus, c:ontinued to open the Sudanese market and production.

(5)

Domestically, the Unregistered Land Act coincided with the 1972 open door or i1!fi1<1/J policy which had codified Sudan's dependence 011 foreign capital (Elnur 2008: 40). Investment into the Arab Breadbasket was not only politically driven by the food stratCb'Y of (;ulf states but also .fi1u111cinll)' fi.,elled by the need to recycle OPEC petro-capital, especially after the 1973 oil crisis had cut off Western market�. Howev�r, expansion was driven not only by the imperatives of a global political economy, but also by the rapid soil depletion the somewhat thoughtless culti­ vation of newly introduced cash crops had caused. Expanding the frontiers of cultivation and eventual environmental degradation led to more land conflict, notably in the Nuba mountains, southern Blue Nik and eastern Sudan (Ayers 20'1(); Suliman 1999a, 1999b, 1999c). In short, through tmsustainable farming, capitalist expansion was dependent upon territorial expansion as long as the economy would remain focused on primary commodity export. This led not only to increased prices and depressed wages but also to the continuation of unsustainable 'short­ tennist' cultivation practices. Tlu:se factors co-detennined the ecologic and economic crisis still ongoing today, which is characterised by an enduring current account deficit, m1ly dismpted by -in retrospect -a short era of oil riches.

After Nimery's fall, the 1986 interregnum of parliamentary democracy led to the rise of lslamist parties, possibly in reaction to socio-economic developments. In 1 989 the continued economic failure led to another coup by an impatient 'mthless business and finance segment of the ruling elite' (Suliman 1994: 19). The finance segment was based on an emerging Islamic banking sector majority-owned by Gulf investors. The Faisal Islamic Bank, for example, is 60% owned by foreign investors. Not only did Islamic banks enjoy t:tx bre:iks not available:: to other banks, but as a result of politically engineered privileges the lending and business practices of Islamic banks 'revolutionised access to credit, and wrested the virtual monopoly of this vital sector from privileged b'TOups (many of whom were of foreign extr,1ction)' (Elnur 2008: 70). In that sense, it was, according to Elnur, the single most important factor explaining the rise of the Islamist movement (ibid.). Its success in negotiating political and tax concessions from the state meant that it eqjoyed a competitive edge over Sudan's established banks, quickly outgrowing them. War, in tum, hanned primary production in Sudan and led to increasing economic pressure on the Khartoum bourgeoisie (or Jellaba), leading to a consolidation of mercantile capitalist activity with Islamic finance, fuelled by a b'TOwing oil income in the Sudanese capital. Accumulated capital, in part due to the endemic state of political instability, moved abroad, however, along with skilled labour and upper middle-class urban population throughout the 1 980s and 1990s, destined for oil-producing Arab states and Europe.

This consolidation of a strong class alliance, based in Khartoum, between ;1gricultural capital, a merchant bourgeoisie and political elites w:ts in fact quite similar to previous Umma and Mahdi administrations. Nimery's socialist experiment can be seen as the exception to the nilc here. What made the NCl''s regime different from its predecessors, though, was its much more pronounced lslamist agenda. Second, not only capital accumulated in the agricultural sector but also :t pctro dollar­ fuelled Islamic finance became major pillars for the regime (Elhiraika 1996; Khaleefa 1993).

However, as capital wants to sec quick rctums on investments, the rapid and violent repl:t­ ccmcnt of more sustainable fonns of production in a subsistence economy by fonns of pro­ duction amenable to surplus extraction continued. Not only did this pcrpe�uate social strain and conflict, it also exhausted ecosystems. The latest two instalments of these policies arc the out­ sourcing of production in Gezira to Eb,yptian st:1te investors, dispossessing fam1ers there (Ali 2010), :md the hydro-engineering and irribration developments in north Sud:tn and 131ue Nile.

Agricultural developments around the Merowc multi-purpose dam project, for instance, have led to the displacement of many Manasir1 Amri-Hamdab and Nubian people far from their

(6)

with a policy ofho11mgc11is:1tion i11 the for111 oflsb111isatio11. Arguably, thus, Hooding currt·nt and

fim1rc hydrn-cngi11ccri11g and ah,ricultm:11 pnljccts follow chc puri>osc 11<>t only of i1Krc:1.�ing pro­

duction, hue also of cransforn1ing livc:lihoods. cxpamling n1echanisacion along with colltrolling

wage-labour rdacions. In su111. chis amoullts co what some c1II 'demographic engineering'

(Hashilll 20 I 0), some of which is said m be achieved by �cctling Eh,ypti:111 f:1rn1cr,; in the Sudan

(Ali 20 I 0). These arc a few cxa111plcs cpito111ising the top-down approach to devclopn1e11t which

explains to sollle degree the various colllplcx and persistent conHicts in tin: coulltry. However, it is worth noting at chis point that the web of pcr,;onal relations as well as transnational c.:01mections which constit11te Kharmu111\ lllilitary-financial complex lllakc the clear idclltification of 1((!n1ry as well

:IS Sfrll(/1/f('S difficult.

2.2.2 South Sudan

Crnnpared to the vast history of foiled, u11sustai11ablc or co11Aict-ricldc11 ahrricultural devclopmcm i11 North Sml:111, South Suda11 h:1s see11 little to no such investmellts or devclop111em in ge11eral, though ple11ty of conHict. Largely owi11g co a policy of neglect bm also through decades of al111ost u11intcrruptcd conHict and hostilities, large awiwltural schcllles arc abscm:1 This rn:1kcs the newly founded Republic of South Sudan a pewliar place, which is Jllarkcdly ditfcrcnt not only frolll its 11orthern neighbour but also fron1 its East Afric:111 m;ighbours Kenya, Uga11da and Ethiopia, South Sudan's main eco110111ic parmer� (Yon go-Bure /;(!

°

)()7}>Foll<-i.:Ving the cstablishmcllt of a sc111i­ auco110111ous govem111c11t in Juba in the 2005 C:o/npl'ehcnsivc Peace Ahrrcc111c11t (CPA), inco111c was largely generated by oil revenues, which translated into one of the highest per capita i11colllcs on the colltinem, compar.1blc to that of South Africa. Par.1doxically, owini; to the legacy of Africa's longest civil war, it also features one of the lowest hu111a11 developlllcllt i11diccs as well as bci11g severely fi,od i11sccurc in a rq,:iou vulncr:1blc to the dfcu.� .of. weather i.lxtrcnics, such :is droughts and Hoods.

Agricultural production and rural livelihoods rclllain by and large based on traditionJlkcause of its variable clilllatc, both spatially as well as telllporally, South Suda11 traditionally. features

changing land-use patterns and a highly mobile population. Li�elihoods art· based on shared land use·. which is the rule ratlil'r· tT1e exception: Tliis 'alsci ii1cludcs the fanning areas of the so­ called Equatori:1 Crccn Bl'lt, where shifting cultivation is conmion. Arguably, these conditions don't lend themselves easily to the introduction of a W estcm-style private property regime, let alone large 111cchaniscd schemes. While c11trcnd1cd in local tradition, shared land-us<.: practic<.:

was never t·mirdy conHict-frt·c and 111any use rights were negotiated using ditkring levels of

violcll(.:c. Currl·lltly, however, it leads to high levels of violence and scores of casualties. De,ades of war have damaged old contlict-rcsolu�ion 111echanisms along with traditional authority while

having proliferated fire arms. Several campaigns of dis:1n11all1c11t have only been partially suc­

<.:essfiil so for (Scholllerus and Allan 20 I Cl: I 0). Thus, conflict :1nd displacclllent have led to the

disoricmation of wide parts of the population and a general dctcrioratio11 of the traditional social order, which has only very inconsistently been replaced by mmkm state structures. In short, Somh Sudan has thus far failed to i111plc1nent Max W cbcr's folllously defined modern state as 'a

ln1111:w co111111unity (that) succcssfolly claims the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical

force within ;qµllcn territory' (Weber 1�91.: ?8). . . . ····-· ·--···

(A1H;�her aspe:� ·i�"cf1�··j;·;c�;;j�,·;��

·-�,i

�1astor:1l (>r agro-pastor:11 ii;�liho�i�\rt,1casurcd by the

output of marketable n,111111oditics, this is by and large a non- productive scc.:tor. rarming is

more traditionally roott·d in ( ;reatcr Equatoria, whc�e soils arc thought to be more fertile, but

l'Ve11 lwrc the legacy of rnnHin has destroyed 111any traditional fonning skills. As far as land-me

p:lltcrns an: concerned, this docs not necessarily lead to more stationary livelihoods lllorc adaptable m capitalist lllodcs of production. On the one hand, 1wnHict has brought 111any

(7)

pastoral conm1t1111t1cs co the region, illl:rcasing pressure on existing land and water resources. ( )11 the other hand, forn,�!s hav�

. t_i.:aditionally adhcr.c.d _ ��> sh_i_�ti•!g .. �ultivation .. Lastly, if existing forms produce hcyond subsistence levels, lllarketing skills arc insufficient and necessary infra­ strucmrc for producer's access to the market is either poor or non-existent, s.� .. that food supply rcn1aim dependent on imports from Kenya and Uganda as well as WFP handot�t�: · ·· · · · ·· · ···

-- · Current South Sudanese devclopmem and agricultur3l policies arc trying to attract FI )I for

the purpose of food production. Beyond local consu111ption, President Kiir and Vice-President Machar poimed to the potential export orientation of production when noting South Sudan's capability of becoming the rc!-,rional food basket, with 'the entire world benefiting it' (Uma 2011)). Notions of Somh Sudan as the rcgion 's breadbasket depend 011 the assumption of 'resource abundance·. notably abundann· of land (Lupai 20 I I). However, the seasonal use of land predudes such an easy and somewhat foregone condusion. Awareness of the historical trajectory of Sud.m's 'n1al-intcgrmion' into the world economy is therefore essential when these polic:ics arc implcn1cntcd.

·': "Having said chat, there arc various obvious differences between north and South Sudan with

the· ·latter being i11corporated into a regional East African economy, rather th:u1 develcipii1g a dcpcndcnc:y-on pcm;- dollars for its ai,,>ric:ultural ·dcvclopmcm·.'.;Equaliy, it is not exposed to the s;1111e din1atic conditio11s as the north and might, therefore, be capable Q[ introducing mechan­ ised agriculture in a niore sustainable manner compared to the unsustainable schclllcs that have led to enviro11111cntal degradation north of the new border. Partly through historical experience, partly through the current debates about land grabs, the South Sudanese leadership is not una­ ware of potential problems (Nhial 2008 ). It aims to introduce legal safeguards against 11011-productive investments or those only directed by high yields rather than food security, such as carbon sinks and biofucls. Equally, South Sudan might not be subjected to a similarly nipacious investment regilllc of lslalllic/(;ulf finance, even though the activities of a venture capital finn like the Jarch Group or the private Ei,,yptian but statc-doll)inated Citadel group, as well as other invcst111c11t activities, give rise to some concern (Deng 201 1 ).

3 The nation, the global and the geopolitical

3.

7

Global capital accumulation

Much of che literature on land grabs has rightly pointed to the issue of 'global' market forces as the core agcm behind the process of land grabs across Africa, which, to some, constitutes a new wave and new fonns of 'pri111itivc accumulation' (Sasscn 20 I 0). Though solllc disagree that the observable fonm of land invcstmenc in South Sudan can be seen as part of the pan-African phenomenon of land grabs (Mosley 2012), the govcrn111c11t of South Sudan's repeated rhetorical

colllmit111e11t to private invcstors5 as the key means of development in the new country begs

solllc questions, not least because it also leaves the notion of a 'right to sclf:.dctermination' incomplete at best. Inflow of private capital to rnlllpcnsatc for lost oil revenue might help South Sudan in its deterll)ination to an independent destiny vis- :1 -vis the north; however, it creates new forms of dependencies, potentially leading to a damaging foreign debt cycle as was showcased in north Sudan. In that sense, the involvement of global co11m1odity markets and the long-term impact of the capital flight from the sub-prime crisis'' 011 rising food p1iccs can be seen as new forms of a phenon1cnon well known to Sudan. In other words, l:ind gr.lbs arc not only a contclllporary phenomenon. They arc but the latest step in a long historical legacy of primitive accumulation happening across the globe with ill)p)ications for both Sudans.

(8)

As was dc.:sc.:ribc.:d above.:, Suda11 's dc.:vdop111c.:11t a11d i11 particular its agricultural dc.:vdop111c.:11t were.: tightly intc.:rwovc.:11 with tht· i11temational political c.:cono111y long before.: oil rc.:vc.:mtc.: Howi11g. Thi� history of i11tnn:1tio11al involvc111c.:nt ca11 be traced back w the colo11ial cstablish-111�'.tlt of cotto11 cultivation which had produced local i11tcrmcdiaries for the risi11g world cco11-0111y of the 19th century. The.: trajectory si11cc.: then has slowly led imo the prolo11gtd state of economic, c.:cologic, social and security crisis still ongoing, i11terruptc.:d by periods of relative.: peace in the 1970s :Hid oil wealth in the 2000s. h>reign i11debtcd11c.:ss and cr.1dc ddicits rc.:maillcd, though. Long go11e were the days of the cottotl-owcd trade surplus of the first post­ indc.:pc.:11dcncc years. This history illustrates how the process of global capital accumul:nioll subjects local social rdatio11s to systc.:111ic pressures. This also applies to the SPLM, which, bcyotld its dcvdopme11talist age11da, is subject to a wider political eco110111ic illlpcrative that necessarily i11volves social contradictions i11hcrent in capitalist developlllcnt per sc. However, while 'global' lllarkct forces certai11ly play a role in understanding the current process of pri­ lllitive acculllulatioll, carried out by a global lllarkct, intc.:mational institutions and local dices, there arc also geopolitical aspects that inAucnce outcomes, which is a ncglec.:cc.:d aspect in lllany analyses.

3.2 Geopolitics

The 111ost obvious and 111ost c.:011m1only referred to geopolitical aspect in Sudan as well as South

Sudan is the dfc.:ct of competition over the access to hydrocarbons, especially betwee11 'Wes­

cern' powers like the USA and 'Asian' players like the Peoplc.:'s Republic of China. As will be demonstrated in the following sc.:c.:tion, resource co111petition alone is insuttic.:ie11t for explaining

the respective Sudan policies of 111:tior powers. Rather, this section will try to analyse.: these policies in their historical�ocial relation cowards one :111other to aeeoum for a nntltitudc.: of

global atld regiollal dyna111ics dctc.:nuilling the actions of external powers in the region. Historically, geopolitics has always constituted a strong component of the history of the rq�ion. This reached from the long-lasting Ebryptian influence.: and domination to the Ottoman Empire's tributary rdation (or Turkiyya) to the British Empire. While these relations of dom­ ination were formalised, post-colonial independence suggested a degree of sclf-dcten11inatio11 that is not necessarily reflected in the scope of action provided to the respective leaderships in Juba and l<hartt>11111. 111 other words, even without mobilising a 11eo-Marxist vocabulary of

'llco-lmpc.:rialism', 'nco-colonialism' or 'E111pire', geopolitical social rd11tit111s fratlle the past and fim1rc.: in the two SudallS alike.

The United States of America

From today's vamagc point it seems ditfkult to believe chat Sudan was a key US ally in the region during the Cold War. It shows, however, the malleability of global social rdations, known as geopolitics, and the value in analysing those. This hist<>ric involvement is reAected in the key contribution to the Cl' A. Arguably, the United States continues to be a detennining factor in the future of both Sudans. Today's US foreign policy ac the Hom of Africa is no longer characterised by Cold War stratc.:gising, however, but by the 'war 011 terror'.

The (;eorge W. Bush administration's 'str.itcgic philanthropy' (Barnes 2005: I(,; Huliaras 200(>), which lc.:d to the administration's c0trnnit111c.:nt to the Sudanese peace process, not only came about as a spontaneous rc.:a<:tion to the terrorist attachs on the USA 011 11 Septe111bcr 200 I

(9/ I I ) but is historic.:ally rooted in a long history of involvclllt:llt in the Sudan (Mamdani 2009; Woodward '.WO<>). Regardless, the strong US position providing the leverage necessary to end

(9)

the w:1r was dfoc.:ted not by a long-term post-Cold War stratq,ry for East Africa. aiming at installing a 'client state', but rather by the inadvcrtcm combination of Cold War legacy co111-micn1c11ts. like those to Uganda and Ethiopia, the perceived imperatives of the war on terror and the rise of the evangelical right in the USA.

The end of the cxtcrn:il 'necessity' of the Cold War had initially left US policy-makers in a state of disorientation towards the whole of Africa but cspe<.:ially in a region as geopoliti<.:ally sensitive as the Horn. This is evidrn<.:ed by the aborted Solllalia mission followed by a wider disengagement under Presidcm Bill Clinton. While West, Central and East Afiica, despite all their contliccs and instability, were arguably more subject to the influence of their respective former colonial powers, the Hom's geopolitics are more fo1gn1entcd. The proximity to natural resources and maritin1e eneri,ry routes makes it subject to co111petition by independent rising post-colonial powers. Notably this applies to the mostly hydro-political relations between Ebrypt and Ethiopia in the i111lllcdiate neighbourhood and, in the periphery, Saudi Arabia, Iran, Israel and until recently Libya.

It is precisely these .11nbitions that had also put them at the cemre of Cold War dynamics, with such dramatic implications for the 'internal' social relations in Sudan (Mallldani 2009). Apart frolll these rivalries the region a,ljaccnt to the enerbry-rich Middle East is of natural geo­ strategic incerest to powers aiming at global reach, but also to snialler middle powers active in the environment. For example, while being geobrraphically far removed, Sudan has always played an important part in the Arab-Israeli conflict, prompting long-lasting Jsr;icli involvement in East Africa and in Uganda especially. Similarly, Sudan currently has to balance its declared friendship with lr:111 with the long-standing financial and religious influence of the more prox­ imate S:mdis, who look at this 'friendship' with disapproval.

Additionally, no clear regional hegemon has emerged, providing ample 'room to m:moeuvre' to all players on the chessboard, including any regime Khartoum has produced (Marchal 20 I 0: 81). I )ue to the geopoliti<.:ally ambiguous post Cold War situation, the US had difficulties 'in defining an overarching set of national interests' which could have provided the context for a more interventionist policy (van de Walle 2009: 1). Consequently, the Clinton administration's policy, preoccupied with peace-making in the Balkans, was one of 'retrenchment and timidity' with the active discouragement of intervention in the Rwandan genocide constituting a possi­ ble low point (van de Walle 2009: 2). Despite its ineffec�iveness, the Bush campaign still criti­ cised Clinton for being too committed to the continen0radoxically, Bush thus turned out cJ'-· be much more pro-active in Africa as a whole, starting with his commitment to fighting HIV/ AIDS. If the increase in aid had come to many as a surprise, the increased engagement culmi­ n:iting in the 2007 creation of a dedicated command for the continent Atiica Conimand (A flt IC:OM, without Ebrypt) can be seen as part of a redefinition of US interests in the continent

-i�o�r.::i.>llT:-As oi)1)6sed·1:o··t"°i'.1e Middle East, the.Africa engil��_1_nent _q_i.ll !!..<.?.�;°!!!f��.fu>.!.1..1.� .. P.�.!!i::!.Y.•_11 a�

...:.was especially the success of the CPA that led many commentators, including many vocal crit­�1tiustifia�le neo-cok>,nia.lisn). St.1rting from what van de Walle calls 'ad hoe hlllnanitarianism' it ics, to describe the administration's record in Africa as a unique success in stark contrast to the

rest of the Bush legacy (Mamdani 201 1 ; van de Walle 2009:

0)>

While the war on terror began focusing more directly on so·inalia, the continued US interest in the-re1,��-;;··;1s� i;1c1�;des both Sudans. South Sud:ii1 a·s a reliable ally i�

·;�;i)p�rt��n;y

·tl;·�

��g�f;�i

-;;iii�;�isati�·n of US Africa policy, epi�o111iscd most clearly by the launching of the Combined Joint

Talks Force - Horn of Africa (CJTF-HOA) in response to the thrc:it of Al Qaeda and affiliates in the region in 2002, but also by direct and indirect military aid as declared in President Barack Oban1a 's latest budget pbtt,J!1t�r�s�.(1�gly: 1�1!.lita.ri:�a.�i?n �!�d a!d b:_came intennin!?l_cd under these I circ��mst�!l_<.:S.S., JO tl1at �.FRl�·:c?./\.11 !low 1��1qages _one-��J1. o� tJ�e. lJ.S.ail!. ��1_c!get to .f'{�c_;i (van de Walle 2009: 1 3))tclatio11s with Khartoum away from the public image arc not in any case as

(10)

_.-drcadtiil as is commrnily believed. The main bo1w of crn1tcmion is humanitarian access and the fact that the USA has not n:movcd K harmtm1 from the list of states �ponsori11g terrorism, as initially promised. More generally. though, the NCP is 110 sn�u1gcr to Washington. Afi:cr the US strikes 011 l<harcou111 in the atien11ath of the Kenyan and Tam;;mia11 embassy bombings, the N< :p leatki,hip has dcmo11str.1ted a highly co-operative spirit, especially with regard to incelligrnce co-opc1�nion, which is wnsidercd vital to US opcrntions in Somalia. ( )tlicial US polit.y, in p:ntiwlar those parts of the Rcpublic:111 party intlucnn:d by the evangelist right and those parts of the I >cmoc1�1ts i11tlue11ced by ln11nanit;1rian lobbyists, continues painting a public image of hostility towards K hartou111 (Mamd:111i 2007, 2009). However, the picture is far from black and white. Similarly, while the US role, especially in the d1;1fti11g of the CPA, is cnicial, its actions have to be understood in relation to other powers' actions and cvcms in the region and globally.

The People's Republic of China

By c.:omrast, China's involvcmem in both Sudans is frequently reduced to pure energy security policy (Mohan and Power 2008). While the heavy invcstmcms in Sudan's oil industry certainly detennine Chinese ( ;overnment's interests in the region, this docs not come in the form of a \trice :mti-American support of Bashir and the NCP.7 Given that 70%, of proven reserves arc in the south, Juba is an equally important partner for China. With independence and the strong tit:s between the SPLM and the US, competition for namr:11 resources and intlut:nct: is certainly a foc..:mr, though the concrete nature this competition may take is unknown. Most likely it will be a matter of considcr.1blc c..:omplexity (Large 2008, 2009) also involving other powers, notably India (Narlikar 2010).

Similar power collstdlatiolls can be found in broader geo-stratq�ic terms beyond the issue of cncrb'Y scn1rity. China's growing external trade requires securing global routes, a policy which has been articulated in the so-called 'String of Pearls' strategy, of which LAPSSET could be a part. While this could just represent legitimate and recognised maritime trade interests (Khurana 2()08), it might equally lead to r.:olllpetitio11 with India and the USA. Military and security implications art: far from clear, though. 111 any case, the fact that it provides roolll for spcrnla­ tion is suttiric11t to make the String of Pearls relevant. For even if there is 110 'hard' sccmity issue at stake, the stratq.,ry exists at least as a perception, which in tum lllight influence naval policies of other powers, like the USA (( ;enz 2005; Pehrson 200(1).

The dialectics of geopolitics

The discussion around the plau·ment of AFRIC( )M and China\ String of Pearls strategy i11 the Indian ( kcan provides two indicators of what underlies the respective ( ;rcat Power strategics in the region beyond resource access. However, these should not be seen as two 'tunnel visions', /lindly followed by these powers indcpcndcm of their cnvim11111cnt. Nor should analysis be limited to a 'global' competition between Beijing and Washingto11r:More likely, the two powc1, arc pn:occupicd with finding a qcw lllodus vivendi .illowing each the continuation of their rcspccrive strategics of accu11n1lati<7This also includes the thus far highly fragile post­ CP A intra-Sudanese rclatiolls, which arc to be strengthened instead of contributing to destabi­ lising the rcgioll with (;rcat Power competition. In fact, lllOSt states will be concerned with post-CPA \tahility - a desire that has hcconie even grcatt·r at a ti111c characterised by an increasing sense of post-rcvolmionary volatility and unpredictability in the Arab world.

This short portrayal of the complexity of global political cr.:o1H>rnic and geopolitical relations i� by 110 means exhaustive. It silllply goc\ to show th:1t policy dcc:isicms arc not taken in a

(11)

vacuum, purely tktcr111i11cd by what Robert Pumam 011cc fa111ously called 'two-level games (Putnam 1988). Rather, they arc the outco111c of a complex web of soc:ial relatious, 'do111estic', 'international' and 'global' in scope, sonH.:tillles part of a wider policy, but also sollletimes ad hoe reactions to other actors and emerging strucwres. Geopolitics is therefore better understood as the diale<.:tical relationship between different historically and geographically specific foreign policies e111crgi11g from a soc:ial substance, rather than pmcly stru<.:turally generated so<.:ially en1pty Great Power c:<>lllpctition (Waltz 1979). While c:o111petitio11 is part of this dialectic, including the c:01npctitiou over n.:sour<.:es for profit, it might equally follow different imper.1tivcs in differellt situations. It is therefore the dialc<.:tical relationship of powers and the unintended consequences this relationship has generated that <.:onstitute the geopoliti<.:al structure into whid1 South Sudan was born. This is what deli111its the new country's scope of action. Withiu the dual structures of global markets and a pre-existing inter-state system South Sudan can adapt, react, i11ttuc11u· and <.:ontribute, but it ca1111ot determine the shape of its futmc entirely independently.

4 Conclusion

An historical perspective 011 the c:011tc111porary process of prilllitivc accu111ulation reveals v:uious dialectical relationships determining the _!l..'l�t11·e ,me.I scope of dcvelop111cnt in the Sudan and the newly independent South Sudan. Tlk. firs_s,,<J these relationships is that with its own history. Historically constituted social - productive - relations continue to influence the CllffCllt trajcc­ tOly of both Sudans. This is not co argue in favour of a path dependency, however, but rather that any analysis of the contemporary policy dilcn1111as requires a thorough search for their his­ co1ical origins. ;>ccond,...,ftolll a classical Marxist perspective, how the relationship between capital ;md direct pruc.f�1ccrs develops is crucial for the future of production and, hence, wealth creation. This relatio11ship needs <.:arcful calibration, usually by the state when undergoing capitalist dcvcloplllcllt. In other words, the establishment of a waged labour force as the basis for a capitalist growth regime will have to scp:iratc direct producers from their means of pro­ duction, illlplying a tremendous social tra11sformation that requires careful negotiation, Third,, the establishment of a private property regime is subject to similar conditions with rcgara;tto la11d rights. How the. carefully crafted South Sudanese land policy will be i111plc111c11ted is crucial in this regard./<;;irs!i. dearly identifying local agency in this process is problematic as it is sub­ ject to an incrcasi11gly volatile global rcgilllc of capitalist accu!llulation. This regime of accu­ mulation is in cum itself embedded within global and regional gcopolitic;1l systems. Political decisions directing the fumrc path of South Sudanese tlcveloplllellt arc therefore thelllsclves p;1rt of a 'global'/'gcop_yliti�al' dialectic, the colllplcxity of which is so111ctimcs difficult to penetrate analytically

(F�/

these difficulties should not obscure the view on an intra-elite c:0111petitio11, carried ouf locally and regionally as well as globally over the sources of suq>lus, with arable land being second only to oil in its desirability. L>eveloplllcntal contradictions arc thus reproduced locally as well as globally, specifically within the agricultural/land dcvcloplllcnt se<.:tor, reaffirming the view that 'pri111itivc acculllulation' has to be seen as :1 permanent, r:uhcr than finite, process.

In the mc:mtimc, development in South Sudan, agiicultural and otherwise, remains in its infa11cy. What solllc lllight sec as a 'privilege of backwardness' provides incentives for devising 'mega projects' for others. This applies in particular when it collies to addrl'ssing the paramount issues of food sccrnity and pressures to divcr.;ify the cconollly away fro111 hydro-carbons.

A1owcvcr, the lesson that South Sudan can learn frolll its fonncr northern fiw is that b.ig_pm-( �.!...more th:111 offering v:1luablc services for the population or a qui<.:k fix u> food sc<.:urity and

other problcn1s, 111orc than anything offer high levels of surplus co investors, which is frequently

--o•--wo--- - ·�•

(12)

siphoned off by markets. Capital docs not ne<.:essarily bendit the local population, who have co buy back serviu·s at inflated rates co a<.:<.:0111modate invcstors' expectations. Historical and con­ temporary experiences in the global north and dsewhcrt· in Africa suggest that devdopmem in

big pn�jects involving foreign imt·rests <.:an have detri111ental etli:cts on con11111111iti5 Capital

thus acrn111ulated, however, will find a way to turn profitable, especially if instability persists

and the institutions of the 11ew state remain weak. Thus, while big projects might see111 an iutuitive rca<.:tion to the current situation, small-sc;1le <.:on1nnmity-based projects nevertheless otter more sustainable forms of development, a more direct return on thc invcstmcnt, but also a safeguard against thc outbreak of similar pattcrns of <.:onAict. This applies to thc expansion of agriculwral production as well as to hydro-engineering and other big projects.

While this d1aptcr has focused on questions of thc relationship between land, social power and thc cnvironn1c11t in -by now -two <.:ountrics, it has to be rccogniscd that the sources of war and instability arc cqually located within the globally and histori<.:ally <.:onstitutcd so<.:ial rclations briefly outlined here.

Notes

1':1rts of this research have been conducted under the EU Fl'7 CLICO project, for dct:1ils see: www. diw.org. The author is gratcfi.tl for the �upport.

2 llcrnal111 (20 1 1 : 83) qumcs Article 5 of the Sl'LM legislation No. 1 of 1983 at length:

The Marxist-Leninist movement known as Sudan's l't·ople's Lib.:r:ition Movcmem shall be the sol.: pL·opl.:'s political organisation established in the i11terest of the oppressed working masses of th<.: Sudan people to liberate the rnulltry from th<.: opprcssiv<.:, com1pt and reactionary bourgeois governm<.:nt of Khartoum.

Thu�. in the early stage� of the struggle, :1r�uably still dominated by the i111perativcs of the Cold War, tht· Sl'LM adopted an ami-capitalisc, r:ithcr than :111ti-northcrn/ Ar:1b, language.

3 This point has hcL·n made by various social th<.:orists, from within hoth Marxist and W.:bcrian tradi­ tions: Wood (2002); Tilly (1990).

4 The Aw<.:il Rice sd1e111e is an <.:xception that proves the rule. le has lO be added chat it is based on Hood irrigation and in the early stag<.:s of donor-funded rd1abilitation.

5 Statement� or thi� natur<.: arc frequently aired by South Sudanese politicians :111d Vice-l'r.:sid<.:nt Ri<.:k Mad1:1r in partirnlar. Ths•rc is a concerted policy pl:in hackin� up such pbns, as cvi,k11ccd by thL� rep<.:ated invitations to invcstms (S11d,111 'J'ri/11111<· 2012h).

<, Th.: crfi:ct of' the liurop<.:an debt crisis has yer to be established :111d cannot, th<.:refor<.:, be discuss.:d here.

7 The most striking cx:m1pk of its rather m1anccd Sudan policy is China's abst<.:ntion when che Security Coundl Resolutio11 rdcn<.:d th<.: I >arfur W:1r Crim<.:s to the ICC in 2005. Notably, the USA cast chc same vote along with llrazil and Al1,;'Cria, whil<.: Russia am\ the Europea11 pcn11a11e11t UN Security Council (UNSC) n11.:111bcrs voted in favour.

References

Abdelkarim, A. (19'J2) l'ri111iri11r Capira/ llm111111/11rio11 ;,, flit' S111/1111, Londo11: Routledg<.:.

Ali, A. A. (20 I 0) 'E1,'Ypt's takeovt·r of Sudan's (;.:zir:1 scheme', S11d1111 Tri/111111·. Omdunnan, 19 I kcemb<.:r. Ami11, S. (1')77) /111pai11/is111 11111/ U11cq11al J>cwl,,1111w11t, New York: Monthly R.:view Pre�-s.

Awad, M. 1 1. (I 971) The t·vollllion of la11dowm·rship i11 the Sudan', 1\tlidd/1' /:'as/ j()Jm111/ 25(2): 2 1 2 -28. Ay<.:rs, A. J. (2010) 'Sll(bn's uncivil war: th<.: global- historical constitution of political violem:c', Rl'vi,·111 if

I\J;ir,111 l',,fitir,,I I iro111>111y 37( 124): 153-71.

11:irncs, S. T. (2005) '(:Johal flows: terror, oil an(I �tratcgic philanthropy', R,·,,it·11, ,!f AJ;ir,111 l'c•lirir,1/ /:'rm11>111y :\2( I 04/ I OS): 235-52.

(13)

llerhanu, I). (;. (20 1 1 ) lmlirutions a111/ lu11cs111u•11t i11 S111/m1: Soci<>-m>m>mir and /11stit11ti()l111/ 1:m111d11ti()ltS

if

Rm•11.,tr11cli<>11 11111/ l)cllt'l<>p111m1, Munster: Lit. Verbg.

Brt'IHH.:r, R. ( I 985) 'The agrari:111 roots of Eump<.:an c:1pitalislt)', in 'I'. 1 1. Aston and S. I I. E. l'hilpin (eds) ·11w /Jrc•1111<'r /)1•/1111c: 1lgmri1111 Class Stm(t11rt· 11111/ l:'w11,,111ir Dc11d<>p111c111 i11 f>rc-flldmtritt/ li11ropc, C:nnbridge:

C:alt)hridge U11iversity Pres.�. pp. 2 I 3-328.

lh1sh, R .• Llujra,

J.

aHd Littkjohn, C. (20 I I ) 'The ;iccult)ulation of dispossession', R,·11it•11,

<

f

!Wim11 f><>litiml liWll()IIIY 38( I 28): 1 87 - ')2.

I k Angdis, M. (2004) 'Scpararing tht· doing and the deed: capital :md che continuous d1arnce<.:r of cndosurt•s', l·list<>riral Matcri11/is111 12(2): 5 7 -87.

l)eng, I), K. (201 I) 'The 11ew froncier - a basdinc survey of large-scale Jami-based i11vestmenL� in Southern Sudan', Oslo, Norwegian People's Aid. Available at: www.npaid.org (accessed 10 April 201 1).

Elhi1:1ika. A. ll. (1996) 'Risk-sharing and chc supply of :1brricultural credit: :1 case study of Islamic finance in

Sudan', Jmm111/ ,?f ll,�rimlt11ral l.:w11<>111irs 47( 1-4): 390-402.

Elnur, I. (2008) C:ont<·stcd S,11/,111: '17w i'<>litir"I Er1>1w111y ,f War 1111d R<·C<>mtrnrlim,, New York: R.oudedge. (;;ari, A. (2012) 'Kenya: release list of thost' displaced by L:111)11 port, s.1ys Abdallah', N11im/1i Star, (> March. (;ere:£, B. (2005) 'C:hi11a builds up st1:1tegic sea lanes', Washin.�l,m Ti1111•.(, 18 January.

Clas.�man, J. (2006) 'Primitive accult)ubtion, :u.:<.:ult)ulatio11 by disposst"!iSio11, acc11111ubtion by "extra-economic" meam', J>rci�rc·ss i11 l·/11111,111 C,·,�<i"'J'l,y 30(5): 608-25.

I l:lrvey, J>. (2003) '/1,c Ntw /111pcri11/is111, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

1 1:lshim, M.

J.

(20 I 0) 'The dams of Northem Smbn and the policy of dcmoh,raphic cnb,inei:ring', /11t<'Tllt1-tim111/ )<>t1flutl ,?f 1\{rim11 Rm11isst111re St11dfrs 5( 1 ): 1 4 8 -60.

I luliaras, A. (2006) 'Evangelists, oil companies, and terrorists: the Uush administration's polic:y towards Sudan', Orbis 50(4): 709-24.

Khaleefa, M. U. (1993) 'Islamic banking in Sudan's rur.11 sector', Jslm11ir I.:«>m>mir Stttdics 1 (1): 37-55. Klrnr.ma, C. S. (2008) 'China's "String uf Pearls" in the Indian Ocean and IL� security i111plications', Stm­

t<:�ir /11/(//ysis 32(1): 1-39.

Larg,'. I). (2008) 'China and the contradictions of "non-interference" in Sudan', R<'1,i1'w ,f /l_f,irt111 l'c>liriml

fr1>1w111y 35( 1 1 5): 93- 10(>.

- -(2009) 'C:hin:1 's Sudan engagement: changing Northern and Southern political trajectories in peace

:ind war', '/1,c C!,i11n Quarterly 199(1): 6 1 0 -2(,.

Lupai, J. K. (20 1 1 ) 'South Sudan potentially the rcgio11's bre:1db:1skec', S11dm1 Tri/11111<·, Juba, 24 August. Avail:1blc ar: www.sudantribune.co111/The-Republic-of-Sot1th-Sudan,39942 (accessed 13 January 2012). - -(2012) 'South Sudan: :1griculturc alternative to oil for development', /ll//l_f,im.n>111. Available at:

http://:1lbfrica.con1/stories/20 I 20221 1323.htlt)I (accessed I April 2012). Luxe111burg, R. (195 I) '/1,c /lw111111/11ti1>11

,!f

Capital, London: Roucledge.

Man1dani, M. (2007) 'The poli1ic.:s of na111ing: genocide, civil war, insurge1H:y', / .1.md,,11 R<"11hw ,f /Jooks 29: 5 -8.

- -(2009) S,wimm t1111I Sttroirmrs, Cape Town: I ISRC Pr<.:ss.

- -(20 I I) 'South Sudan: rethinking citizenship, sovcreiw1ty :md self-deten11in:1tion ', />11111bnz11k11 N<'IIIS

527 (05-()4).

Marchal, R. (20 I 0) 'The regional dimension of Sudanese politic.:s', in I lcinridi Boll Stiftung (ed.) S11d1111 -Nt> /:,1sy Wa)' A/mu/, Uerlin: H. B. Foundation, pp. 79-96. •

Marx, IC (1981) Capital: II Critique

,if

f>t>litir,1/ f:'co11t>11ty, Vo/ I, London: Penguin in :ISS(>c:iation with Ntw /.1.:fr Re,,icr,,.

Mohan, G. and Power, M. (2008) 'New Afric:m choices' The politics of Chinese engagement', Rt:11ic111

,if

lljric,111 />olitiml f.'ico11(),ny 35( 1 15): 23- 42.

Mosley,

J.

(2012) 'l'eace, bread and land -agricultural investments in Ethiopia and the Sudans', Chatham I louse briding paper, London: Ch:uham House.

Narlibr, A. (2010) 'India's rise t<> power: where docs East Africa fit in?' R<·1,it·11,

,!f

/l_/;ic1111 f>1>/itirt1/ iiw111>111J' 37(126): 451-(,4.

Nhial, N. D. (2008) 'I low docs the govcrnmenc of Southern Sudan design the necessary regulatory fra­ mework tO attract 1:D1 into the agricultural sector?' master's thesis, Centre for Enerh'Y, Petroleum, :1nd Mineral Law and Policy. Dundee: University of Dundee.

l'ehmm, C.

J.

(200(,) 'String of pearls: meeting the challi:nge of China's risini.: power across the Asian

litwr.11', Strategic Studies Institute US Anny War College.

Putnam, R. D. (I 988) 'Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-levd ga111n', illtm111lii>1111/ o��(//iiz,1/ic>11 42(03): 427-60.

(14)

S:iss,·11. S. (20 I 0) 'A sav:ig,· sorti11g of wi1111,·1-s :111d losns: t·o11t,·111JH>r:11y v,·1-sio11s or pri,niliv,· :u·n11nul:i­

tio11 ·, ( ,'/o/1c1/i::,11i,>11.< 7 ( 1 - 2): 2:1- 50.

Srhc>in,·rus, M. :i11d All:111, T. (20 I 0) 'Somhcrn Sudan at odds wirli itself: dyn:1111ics of <.:011llin and pre­

dic:1111<·nts of pcan:'. I>. S. h1stiu1rc, London School of' E<.:onmnit·, and l'olitic:11 Sriem·,·.

S111ith, A. (11)82) '11"· W,·,,/1/1 c!f'N,11i,>m: /!1>11/.:.� t-.1. Lo11do11: l',·11gui11.

S,11/m, Tri/111111' (2012:i) 'Mat:har urges Wall Su·e,·t inwstor, w work in South Sud:111'. S111/m1 '/'ri/111111·, l'aris, 9 March.

- -(20l2h) 'South Sudan to host fon:ign inws1111,·m rnnfi:r,·m:c', Sr,d,111 '/'ri/ir111C·, Juba, 9 March. Suli111an, M. (1')')4) 'Civil war in the Sudan: the i111pan of ,·c.:ologfral dcg,�abtion', Environmem :111d

( :0111lin l'n�j,·,·l (EN< :c )I').

--( I ')91):i) 'Civil w:ir i11 Sudan: the in1pat:t of ec.:ologi,:al dei,:rad:1tio11', in (;, l<d,hedc (,·d.) S,11/1111 's l'ri·-1/ir,r,m·111: <:i,,il W,,r, Di.<('lc1nwc·111 c1111/ lir,>l,i�irc1/ Dc:�r111forie>11, Aldcrshot: Ashgacc, pp. 8 8 -107.

--( I ')<J<Jh) /:w/c\�Y, l'<>litir.< 11111/ Vi<>lc11r <:m,flirr, Lo11don: Zed Books.

- -(l')')'Jc.:) Th,· Nuba 11muntains ofSuda11: re,ourt:L' ac<.:css, viok-iu ,:011tlic1 and idcmity', in I). Buc.:kks (ed.) C11ltiv,11i11.� Jlc11ff: C:<>1!f/i,., c1111/ C:ol/11/1e1m1i,m i11 N11r1mtl Rc.1011m· 1\t/,1111!�<'/llrllf, Washington, l>C: World Bank.

Tilly, C. (19')()) C:C>mic>11, Cr111i1c1/, c1111/ li11mpt'1111 Stt1f<'.<, ,II> 'J'J/)-/'J!)(), Oxford: lll:H.:kwdl.

U111a,

J.

A. (20 I 0) 'Exploit South Suda11 's abu11d:1nt rcsourc.:cs, l'rcsidcm Kiir tells inv,·stors', S,ul,111 '/'ri/i1111c, Juha, :I ( ktoha.

USAII) :111d l'an1ine E:irly Warning Syste111 Network (2012) 'Agro-di111:1tic 111onimring'. Online·. Avaibhk• at: wwwJews.11ct/l'agc,/i111:1gcryho111c.aspx?n1:1p=O (:u.:r.:csscd I O J:1nu:11y 2012).

v:111 de Walle, N. (200')) 'US policy toward, Afric1: the Bush legacy and the Ob:1111a :1d111inistr:1tion',

!l/;ir,111 1\(li1ir.< I 09( 4:14): 1-21.

Waltz, I<. N. (1')7')) '/1u-ory c>( /111m1,11i,>11,,/ />t1/i1fr.,, llc·ading, MA: Addison-Wl•slcy.

Wehcr, M. (1991) l'm111 Max Wl'i1cr: l:ssay.< i11 S,,rit>fc\1/Y, London: Routledge.

WFI' and 1:Ao (2012) l'!l()/WJ:/1 Crop mul l'c>t>d Smtrity 1lrn·s.<m(·111 Missim, r,, So111/1 S11d1111, llo111,·: World

l'ood l'row:111111,e a11d Food a11d Awicultural Ori.::111isation. Online. Av:iilablc at: lmp://doc.:um,·ms.wfp.

org/sldlc11t/gro11ps/public.:/docun1cmsh-na/wfj>244<JO I .pd!' (accessed 22 l'ehrua1y 2012). Wood, E. (I ')')')) '/111' Or(�i11 uf' <:api1alis111, New York: Momhly Review Press.

--(2002) '( :Johal t:apital. national stat,·s', in M. Rl1pcn :1nd 1 1. Smith (eds) I listc>riml M,1rc·ric1/is111 11111/ ( :1c>l111/is,11im1, London: Routledge.

Woodward, I'. (200(,) I IS l'orc(1/fl /1t>liry 111,d r/1<' I ft>m ,f 11.fiim, Aldershnt: Ashgatc.

Yorigo-Burc, II. (2007) /:'rc>m>111ir /)cw!t>pmmt ,!f'Sc>111/wm S111/,111, Lanh:1111, Ml): University Press of Amerir.:a.

York, C:. (2012) • Africa's ambitious 111ega- pon pmjc·ct shrouded in skq>tir.:is111',

·nw

(;fo/1c• aud 1\tlc1il, Tor-omo, C, Mardi.

Referanslar

Benzer Belgeler

bu katkl maddelerinin bUyumeyi te~vik etmeleri ya- nlnda insan ve hayvan sagllglnl ciddi olarak tehdit eden bazl Van etkileri de ortaya ~lkml~llr (Teller ve

233 sayılı KHK’de, KİK’ler içinde anonim şirket kurmak yalnızca bankacılık sektörüne özel bir düzenleme iken yeni düzenlemede tüm Kamu İktisadi Kuruluşları

Bu araştırmanın amacı, lisans düzeyinde turizm eğitimi gören öğrencilerin kişilik özellikleri ile turizm mesleğine yönelik düşünceleri arasında ilişkinin

7,2 derece dönüş kabiliyetli ve haliyle hassasiyeti pekte yüksek olmayan bir adım motoru olup genelde piyasada sıklıkla ve kolaylıkla bulunabilen M11 serisi bir step

Türk sanatının plastik öğeleri arasında sıraladığımız, bitki motifleri, geometrik şekiller, insan yüzleri veya yarı insan-yarı hayvan temsillerinin yanı sıra yazı

Bu nedenle, ülke içinde tüm illerin turizm sektörü için önemli olan turistik alanları belirlenmesi ve belirlenen önem derecesine göre turizme yön

Öğrencilerin öğrenme günlüklerine ayırdıkları zamanlar incelendiğinde başarısı yüksek öğrencilerin tekrar edip, kendi notları okuyarak yazdığı bu nedenle

Gazete ve dergi yazılarını düzenli olarak takip etme oranı değişkeninin; öğrencilerin evrensel değerlere ilişkin tutumları üzerinde öntest sonuçlarına göre manidar