• Sonuç bulunamadı

Optimal capital income taxation in infinitely-lived overlapping generations economies

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Optimal capital income taxation in infinitely-lived overlapping generations economies"

Copied!
38
0
0

Yükleniyor.... (view fulltext now)

Tam metin

(1)

OPTIMAL CAPITAL INCOME TAXATION IN

INFINITELY-LIVED OVERLAPPING GENERATIONS ECONOMIES

A Master’s Thesis

By

ORKHAN HASANALIYEV

THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

BILKENT UNIVERSITY

Ankara

July 2001

(2)

(3)

OPTIMAL CAPITAL INCOME TAXATION IN INFINITELY-LIVED OVERLAPPING GENERATIONS ECONOMIES

The Institute of Economics and Social Sciences of

Bilkent University

by

ORKHAN HASANALIYEV

In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of MASTER OF ECONOMICS

in

THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS BILKENT UNIVERSITY

ANKARA July 2001

(4)

I certify that I have read this thesis and have found that it is fully adequate, in scope and in quality, as a thesis for the degree of Master of Arts

--- Dr.Sabit Khakimzhanov Supervisor

I certify that I have read this thesis and have found that it is fully adequate, in scope and in quality, as a thesis for the degree of Master of Arts

--- Assist. Prof. Dr. Erdem Başçı Examining Committee Member

I certify that I have read this thesis and have found that it is fully adequate, in scope and in quality, as a thesis for the degree of Master of Arts

---

Asist. Prof. Dr. Süheyla Özyıldırım Examining Committee Member

Approval of the Institute of Economics and Social Sciences

--- Prof. Dr. Kürşat Aydoğan Director

(5)

iii

ABSTRACT

OPTIMAL CAPITAL INCOME TAXATION IN INFINITELY-LIVED OVERLAPPING GENERATIONS ECONOMIES

Orkhan Hasanaliyev M. A. in Economics

Advisor: Assist. Prof. Dr. Sabit Khakimzhanov July 2001

This paper analyzes optimal capital income taxation in infinitely-lived overlapping generations economy for both cases when government has the ability to tax capital and labor income of individuals of different vintages differently and when it has no such an ability. In such an economy with the commitment technology I find that optimal long-run capital income tax is zero fot both cases. For a special caso of additively seperable utility functions, I find that if the government has rich set of fiscal instruments, then capital income tax is zero even along the transition path.

Keywords and phrases: Optimal Taxation, OLG, Ramsey Equilibrium,

(6)

iv

ÖZET

EN İYİ SERMAYE KAZANÇLARI VERGISININ UZUN ÖMURLU ÇAKIŞAN NESILLER MODELINDE BELIRLENMESI

Orkhan Hasanaliyev Ekonomi Bölümü Yuksek Lisans Danışman: Dr. Sabit Khakimzhanov

Temmuz 2001

Bu araştırma uzun ömürlü çakışan nesiller ekonomilerinde hükümet farklı nesillerin sermaye ve emek kazaçlarını farklı vergilendirebilme mekanizmasına sahibken ve böyle bir mekanizmadan yoksunken, sermaye kazaçlarının optimal vergilendirmesini ele almaktadır. Böyle bir ekonomide, hükümet sözüne sadıkken, her iki durum için de optimal verginin sıfır olduğu bulunmuştur. Fayda fonksyonu toplamaya göre ayrılabılır olduğu durumu için, hükümet farklı nesilleri farklı vergilendirme olanağına sahibken geçiş döneminde dahi sermaya kazanç vergisi sıfır olarak bulunmuştur.

Anahtar kelimeler ve ifadeler: Optimal Vergilendirme, Çakışan Nesiller,

(7)

v

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I would like to express my sincere gratitude to Sabit Khakimzhanov for his excellent supervision. His patience and expert guidance bring my research up to this point. I am grateful to Erdem Başçı, Süheyla Özyıldırım and Neil Arnwine for showing keen interest to the subject and matter and accepting to review this thesis. And my special thanks to Semih Koray from whom I learned what means to be a good academician.

I am grateful to my family for their love and encouragement.

I owe special thanks to my friends, Mehmet Germeyanoglu, Zeynal Karaca, Yavuz Arslan, Ö. Faruk Baykal, Zafer Akin, who were with me during my study.

(8)

vi

Table of Contents

Abstract………iii Özet ………iv Acknowledgements………v Table of Contents……….vi CHAPTER I: NTRODUCTION………1

CHAPTER II: THE MODEL 2.1 The Basic Structure………..4

2.2 Competitive Equilibrium……….8

CHAPTER III: OPTIMAL FISCAL POLICY 3.1 Ramsey Equilibrium………10

3.2 Characterization of Optimal Policies………...16

3.3 Steady State………..19

3.4 Steady State for Vintage Specific Taxes………..20

3.5 Additively Separable Utility Functions………21

3.6 Comparison with other Models………22

CHAPTERIV:CONCLUSIONS……….26

(9)

1

1 Introduction

One of the fundamental questions in tax policy literature is whether or not to tax the capital income and if yes at what rates. The traditional view for optimal capital income taxes were that it is not zero. Moreover, it held that capital income should be taxed heavily. In contradiction with this view Judd (1985) and Chamley (1986) argued that in the long-run optimal tax on capital income tends to zero.

Judd (1985) found a zero optimal long-run capital income tax rate for steady state in dynamic general equilibrium with heterogeneous infinitely lived agents and nonseparable preferences. Chamley (1986) showed for the infinitely-lived agents model that the long run tax on capital income tends to zero. Chari, Christiano and Kehoe (1991) analyzed optimal policy in stochastic models. Optimal capital income taxation in endogenous growth models with physical and human capital was analyzed by Jones, Manuelli and Rossi (1993, 1997). For overlapping generations model with finitely lived agents Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999) and Erosa and

(10)

2

Gervais (1998) showed that under certain homotheticity and separability conditions it is optimal not to tax capital income in steady state.

The intuition behind the optimality of not taxing capital income in steady state is that taxing capital income in period t+1 is equivalent to taxing consumption at a higher rate in period t+1 than in period t. Therefore, a positive tax on capital income in a steady state is equivalent to an ever-increasing tax on consumption. And such a tax on consumption cannot be optimal.

All the above optimal capital taxation analyses were made under commitment environment, i.e. in the environment where government can commit to its policies. For the no commitment case, Benhabib and Rustichini (1997) and Phelan and Stachetti (2001) showed that in the steady state capital tax rate may be positive and steady state capital may be different from that which would attain with full commitment.

In this paper, I investigate optimal capital income taxation for infinitely lived overlapping generation model. Without making additional assumptions about utility function, it is generally optimal to positively tax the capital income in the steady state for finitely lived overlapping generation models. In this paper, I analyze whether it is the case for infinitely lived overlapping generation models. In addition, I investigate optimal capital income taxation problem for the both cases when

(11)

3

government taxes individuals’ incomes uniformly across generations and for the case without such a restriction.

The thesis is organized as follows. The next chapter introduces the economy. The third chapter characterizes optimal fiscal policy and steady state capital income taxes. And concluding remarks are presented in the last chapter.

(12)

4

2 THE MODEL

2.1 The Basic Structure

Consider an economy in which there are an infinite number of time periods, t, indexed by positive integers. The economy is populated by overlapping generations of identical individuals. An individual born on date υ (the individual’s “vintage”) lives forever. The population is assumed to grow at constant rate n per period, so at any time t there is Nt=(1+n)tN0 individuals alive. It is convenient to assume that the

economy starts at t=0 and N0=1. The individuals of vintage υ are not linked through

operative intergenerational transfers to the individuals of pre-existing vintages.

In each period the economy has two goods: a consumption-capital good and a labor. The objective of an individual born in period υ≥0 is given by

∞ = − − − υ υ υ υ β t t t t t t U(c ,1 l ) , , (1)

(13)

5

where ct,t-υ and lt,t-υ denote consumption and labor supply of the individual of

vintage υ at period t. We assume that 0<β<1 and that the utility function U(ּ,ּ) is increasing in both arguments, twice differentiable, strictly concave, bounded above and satisfies Inada conditions.

∞ = − ) 1 , (

limUc c l as c→0 , for all l and

−∞ = − ) 1 , (

limUl c l as l→1 , for all c

where Uc and Ul denote the partial derivatives of the utility function with respect to

consumption and labor, respectively.

Individuals are endowed with one unit of labor in each period of their life.

Let lt denote date t aggregate per capita labor input, which is total labor supplied by

individuals divided by the total population. So, t t t t t t t t t t n nl n nl n nl l l ) 1 ( ) 1 ( .... ) 1 ( 1 ,0 2 , 1 , , + + + + + + + = − − − (2)

where lt,t-υ denotes labor supply of the individual of vintage υ at period t≥ υ.

Applying the same procedure for consumption, capital and debt, we denote by ct, kt, bt the aggregate per capita consumption, capital and debt at time t, respectively.

(14)

6

At each date there is a unique produced good that can be used for private consumption, government consumption, or as capital. The technology to produce goods is represented by constant returns to scale production function f(kt,lt), where kt

and lt denote the levels of aggregate per capita capital and labor, respectively.

Government consumption, gt, is exogenously given.

Feasibility requires that the resource constraint should be satisfied, i.e. total consumption plus investment must be less then or equal to aggregate output:

) , ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( t 1 t t t t t n k k g f k l c + + + − −δ + ≤ (3)

where 0<δ<1 is the depreciation rate of capital, and all variables are expressed in per capita terms.

Government expenditures are financed by proportional taxes on the income from labor and capital and by government debt. Tax rates on individual υ labor and capital income are denoted by τt,t-υ and θt,t-υ , respectively. Also it is assumed that at

each date the tax rates on labor and capital are independent from the vintage of individuals. Hence, taxes are not vintage specific, within the same period government taxes each individual labor and capital incomes at the same rate.

So, for any t

υ ν υ ν θ θ τ τ − − − − = = t t t t t t t t , , , , for ν≠υ and ν,υ≤t.

(15)

7

Government issues bonds with one-period maturity. bt,t-υ is the government

debt held by individual υ at time t, bt is the aggregate per capita debt and Rb,t is its

return. Note that, since newly born individuals aren't linked by altruism to individuals of earlier vintage, they are born owning no financial wealth, so bt,0=0.

Except for the individual of vintage 0, for whom b0,0 is given. The government

budget constraint is t t t t t t t t t t b b g n b w l r k R, + =(1+ ) +1+ τ +θ ( −δ) . (4)

An individual υ budget constraint is

υ υ υ υ υ υ − + +− τ − θ δ − − − + + t + tt + t t = tt tt + + − t ttt + bt t t t c k w l r k R b b 1, 1 . 1. 1 (1 ) . (1 (1 )( )) , . ,. (5)

where rt and wt are the before-tax returns on capital and labor, and

1+(1-θt )(rt-δ) is the gross return on capital after tax and depreciation, for simplicity

denote it by Rk,t . Note also that kt,0=0, for all υ>0 and k0,0 is given.

Firms in this economy maximize profits:

t t t t t t l wl rk k f( , )− − max . (6)

(16)

8

The first-order conditions for (6) imply that before-tax return on capital and labor equal to their marginal products, i.e.

) , ( t t k t f k l r = (7) ) , ( t t l t f k l w = . (8)

The government's objective is to maximize the social welfare which is defined as the discounted sum of individual lifetime welfares,

∞ = − − − ∞ = − υ υ υ υ υ υ β γ t t t t t t U(c ,1 l ) max , , 0 (9)

where 0<γ<1 is the intergenerational discount factor.

2.2 Competitive Equilibrium

Let πt=(τt,θt) denotes the government policy at t, and let π denotes the policies for all t. Let xt,t-υ=(ct, t-υ lt, t-υ kt+1,t+1-υ,bt+1,t+1-υ) denotes an allocation of individual υ at time t≥ υ, and let xυ denote an allocation of υ for all t, and let x denote an allocation for all

υ for all t. Let (wt, rt, Rb,t) denotes a prices at t, and let (w, r, Rb) denote a price

(17)

9

A competitive equilibrium for this economy is a policy π, an allocation x and price system (w, r, Rb), such that

1) given the policy and the price system, the resulting allocation maximizes individual υ utility, (1), subject to his budget constraint (5), for all υ,

2) the price system satisfies equations (7) and (8),

3) the government budget constraint (4) is satisfied for all t, 4) and the aggregate feasibility constraint (3) is satisfied for all t.

(18)

10

3 OPTIMAL FISCAL POLICY

3.1 Ramsey Equilibrium

In order to characterize competitive equilibrium, I use the primal approach to taxation (Atkenson and Stiglitz (1989)). The idea of this approach is to define the problem of choosing optimal taxes as a problem of choosing allocations subject to constraints, which capture the restrictions on the type of allocations that can be supported as a competitive equilibrium for some choice of taxes.

Consider now the policy problem faced by the government. Suppose that there is an institution or commitment technology through which government, in period 0, can bind itself to a particular sequence of policies once and for all. To model such a commitment we assume that government chooses a policy π at the beginning of time and then the consumers choose their allocations. This means that allocations rules are sequences of functions x(π)=(xt,t-υ(π)) that maps policies π into allocations x(π).

Price rules are sequences of functions w(π)=(wt(π)) , r(π)=(rt(π)), Rb(π)=(Rb,t(π))

(19)

11

Since the government needs to predict how individuals’ allocations and prices will respond to its policies, individuals allocations and prices must be described by rules that associate government policies with allocations.

Definition: A Ramsey equilibrium is a policy π and an allocation rule x(·) and price rules w(·) and r(·) that satisfy the following two conditions:

1) the policy π maximizes

∞ = − − − ∞ = − υ υ υ υ υ υ β π π γ t t t t t t U(c ( ),1 l ( )) max , , 0 (10)

subject to the government constraint (4) with allocations and prices given by x(π),

w(π), r(π) and

2) For every π', the allocation x(π'), the price system w(π'), r(π') and Rb(π') the

policy π' constitute competitive equilibrium.

Proposition 1 (The Ramsey Allocation) The consumption and labor allocations in the Ramsey equilibrium solve the Ramsey problem

∞ = − − − ∞ = − υ υ υ υ υ υ β γ t t t t t t U(c ,1 l ) max , , 0

(20)

12

and implementability constraints:

2) )( , , ) ( , ,0 , ,0 0 , , , υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ β U c U l U Rb b Rk k t c t t l t t c t t t t t + = +

∞ = − − − − − for all υ (11) 3) 0 , 0 , , , t t t t t t l c l c U U U U = − − υ

υ for all t and υ≤t (12)

4) 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 t t t t t t c c c c U U U U + − − + + = υ

υ for all t and υ≤t (13)

Proof: In the Ramsey equilibrium, the government must satisfy its budget constraint

taking as given the allocation rule x(π). These requirements impose restrictions on the set of allocations the government can achieve

I first show that a competitive equilibrium must satisfy (3), (11), (12), (13).

Firstly to show that resource constraint is satisfied, all individuals’ budget constraints, who alive at period t, are added, so that we get an aggregate budget constraint, t t k t b t b t t t t t t c n k w l R b R k b n) 1 (1 ) 1 (1 ) , , , 1 ( + + + + + + = −τ + + . (14)

Summing (14) with the government budget constraint (4), we get

t t t t t t t n k g wl r k c +(1+ ) +1+ = +(1−( −δ)) . (15)

(21)

13

Using (7) and (8), we have the following resource constraint, ) , ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( t 1 t t t t t n k k g f k l c + + + − −δ + = .

Next consider the allocation rule x(π). The necessary and sufficient conditions for

c,l,k and b to solve the individuals problem are given as follows: Let λt,t-υ denote the

Lagrange multiplier on the individual υ budget constraint (5) at period t. Then these conditions are given by (5) with first-order conditions for consumption and labor

0 , , − − = − − υ υ λ β c υ tt t t t U (16) 0 ) 1 ( , , + − − = − − tt t t l t U w t t λ τ β υ υ υ (17)

first-order conditions for capital:

0 1 , 1 , 1 , + = −λttυ λt+ t+υRkt+ (18) first-order conditions for debt:

0 1 , 1 , 1 , + = −λttυ λt+ t+υRbt+ (19)

and transversality conditions 0

(22)

14

0

limkt,tυλt,tυ = as t→∞ (21)

Multiplying consumer’s budget constraint with λt,υ and summing over t and using

(18) and (19) gives

∞ = − − − + = − + υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ λ τ λ t k b t t t t t t t t, (c, w(1 )l, ,0(R , b ,0 R , k ,0) And using (16) and (17), we get

) ( ) ( , , , ,0 , ,0 0 , , , υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ β U c U l U Rb b Rk k t c t t l t t c t t t t t + = +

∞ = − − − − −

Using (16) and (17) for υ=t, we get

) 1 ( 1 0 , 0 , t t l c w U U t t τ − − = (22)

Since right-hand side doesn’t depend on υ, we have

0 , 0 , , , t t t t t t l c l c U U U U = − − υ υ

Similarly using (16) and (18) or (19), we get

1 , 1 0 , 1 , 1 + = + t k c c R U U t t β (23)

(23)

15 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 t t t t t t c c c c U U U U + − − + + = υ υ

Thus, (3), (11), (12) and (13) are necessary conditions that any competitive equilibrium must satisfy.

Conversely, given any allocation {ct,t-υ , lt,t-υ , kt+1,t+1-υ} for all t and υ≤t that satisfy

(3), (11), (12) and (13), we can construct the competitive equilibrium as follows: Define before-tax prices as

) , ( t t k t f k l r = ) , ( t t l t f k l w =

And define after-tax prices as

) 1 ( 1 0 , 0 , t t l c w U U t t τ − − = 1 , 1 0 , 1 , 1 + = + t k c c R U U t t β and let λ υ =β −υ υ t t c t t

t, U , for all t and υ≤t.

Then by construction {ct,t-υ , lt,t-υ , kt+1,t+1-υ}satisfies individuals first-order conditions

(16), (17), (18) and (19).

Defining recursively for υ=0,1,2,…

υ υ υ υ υ υ τ − θ δ − − − + +− − + +1,t 1 = t(1− t)t,t +(1+(1− t)( t − )) t,t + b,t t,tt,tt 1,t 1 t w l r k R b c k b

(24)

16

To show that government budget constraint is satisfied multiply each individual’s, who at period t, budget constraint by t

t n n n ) 1 ( ) 1 ( + + −υ

and sum up them over υ. Then, we get ) )) )( 1 ( 1 ( ) 1 ( ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( 0 ,. . , . 0 1 . 1 , 1 , 1

= = − − − − − + + − − + + − + − − + + − + + = + + + + t t t t b t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t b R k r l w n n n k c b n n n υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ δ θ τ k R b R l w k n b n ct +(1+ ) t+1+(1+ ) t+1 = t(1−τt)t + b,t t + k,t Rewriting feasibility constraint as

t t t t t t t t n k k g wl rk c +(1+ ) +1−(1−δ) + = +

and subtracting from the previous one, we get

t t t t t t t t t t b b g n b w l r k R, + =(1+ ) +1+ τ +θ ( −δ)

3.2 Characterization of Optimal Policies

Let µυ be the Lagrange multiplier associated with implementability constraint and

embed this constraint into the social welfare function and denote by

)) ( ( )) ( ( , , , , ,0 , ,0 , , , υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ β U µ U υc U υl µ U υ R b R k W b k t c t t l t t c t t t t t t t t t + − + + =

∞ = − − − − − − − (24

(25)

17

∞ =0 max υ υ υ γ W (25)

Subject to resource constraint (3), and implemantability constraints (11), (12) and (13).

Let γtρ

t , γtηt,t-υ, γtϕ t,t-υ be Lagrange multipliers on the resource constraint (3), and

implemantability constraints (12) and (13). The first-order conditions for Ramsey problem are: For all t 0 ) 1 ( ) 1 ( , 1 , 1 , , 1, 1 , 1 , 1 = − − − + + + − − −− − − − − l c t t t c c t t t c c t t t t t t ctt n H tt H t t H tt n n W υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ γ ρ γ ϕ γ ϕ γ η γ wrt [ct,t-υ] for all 0≤υ<t (26) 0 ) 1 ( ) 1 ( , 1 , 1 , , 1, 1 , 1 , 1 = − − − + + − − − −− − − − − l l t t t c l t t t c l t t t t t t t ltt w Htt Ht t Htt n n n W υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ γ ρ γ ϕ γ ϕ γ η γ wrt [lt,t-υ] for all 0≤υ<t (27) 0 ) 1 ( ) 1 ( 1 1 1 + = − + + t+ kt+ t t tρ n γ ρ δ f γ [kt+1] (28)

= − = − = − − + + t l c t t t t c c t t t t t c t t t t t t n H H n W 0 , 0 , 0 1 , , 0 , υ υ υ υ υ υ η γ ϕ γ ρ γ γ [ct,0] for υ=t (29)

= − = − = − − + + t l l t t t t c l t t t t t t l t t t t t t n H H n W 0 , 0 , 0 1 , , 0 , υ υ υ υ υ υ η γ ϕ γ ω ρ γ γ [lt,0] for υ=t (30) where υ υ υ υ = − − − + − − ct lt ctt ltt l t t U U U U H , , 0 ,

, log log log

log

(26)

18 υ υ υ = + − − + +− + − − ct ct ct t ctt c t t U U U U H , 1 , 1 0 , 1 ,

1 log log log

log

, (32)

Differentiating γυW with respect to υ ct,tυand ct+1 t,+1−υ, and dividing one to the other and using (26), we get

For the left-hand side, multiply it by β + +υ + υ

t t t t t k c c R U U , 1 1 , 1 / , and denote by υ υ υ υ υ υ − − − − − − + = t t t t t t c t t lc t t cc c t t U l U c U M , , , , , , (34)

For the right-hand side, multiply it by

) 1 ( ) 1 ( 1 1 n f t k t t + + − + + ρ δ γρ and denote by t t l c t t c c t t c c t t c t t n n n H H H Z tt t t tt ) 1 ( ) 1 ( 1 , 1 , 1 , , , 1 , 1 , + + + + = − − −− − − − − − − − υ υ υ υ υ ρ γη ϕ γϕ υ υ υ (35) then we have l c t t t c c t t t c c t t t t t t l c t t t c c t t t c c t t t t t t t t lc c t t cc c t t t lc c t t cc c t c c t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t H H H n n n H H H n n n l U U c U U l U U c U U W W υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ η γ ϕ γ ϕ γ ρ γ η γ ϕ γ ϕ γ ρ γ µ β µ β − + + − − + + − − − − − − + + − + + − + + − + + − − − − − + + − − + + + − − + + + + − + + − − − − − − − − + + − + + − + − − − − − − + + − − − + + = = + + + + + + = 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 1 , 1 1 , 1 1 , 1 , , , , 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 1 , 1 , 1 1 1 1 1 1 , 1 , 1 1 , 1 1 , 1 1 , 1 1 , , ) 1 ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( )) ( ( )) ( ( (33)

(27)

19

(

1

)

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 , 1 , 1 , 1 , + +  − +       + + =         + + + + − + + − − + + − t t c k t t c t t k c t t c t t f Z Z R M M δ µ µ µ µ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ υ (36)

We call the term c t t c t t c t t M U W υ υ υ υ υ µ µ − − − = + + , ,

, 1 as the general equilibrium expenditure

elasticity. This elasticity captures the distortions relevant for setting taxes on capital income in general equilibrium.

So,

Proposition 2: Capital tax rate are different from zero unless c t t c t t M M ,υ = +1,+1υ and c t t c t t Z Z,υ = +1,+1υ. 3.3 Steady State

Now suppose that the solution to the Ramsey problem converges to a steady state. Unlike OLG models with finitely-lived agents, in our model consumption and labor supply of individuals are constant over their lifetimes. So the implementability constraints (12) and (13) are not binding in steady state, thus the Langrange multiplier on these constraints, φ and η are zero. Therefore, from (34) and (35)

c t t c t t Z Z,−υ = +1,+1−υ=0 and c t t c t t M M ,−υ = +1,+1−υ.

(28)

20 Thus,

Proposition 3: If the solution to the Ramsey problem converges to a steady state,

then in the steady state the capital income tax rates are zero.

3.4 Steady State for Vintage Specific Taxes

Now, consider the case when the government be allowed to tax individuals of different vintages differently, i.e. it may be that

υ ν υ ν θ θ τ τ − − − − ≠ ≠ t t t t t t t t , , , , for ν≠υ and ν,υ≤t

In this case, we need not impose the implementability constraints (12) and (13) to the Ramsey problem. So the first parentheses on the right-hand side of eq (36) will reduce to 1.

Corollary: With the vintage specific taxes, if the solution to the Ramsey problem

converges to a steady state, then in the steady state the capital income tax rates are zero.

So, the optimality of capital taxes, in the steady state does not depend on the richness of government policy instruments.

(29)

21

For certain specific utility functions, Chamley (1986) showed that in infinitely-lived agent model that the optimal capital income taxes are zero after the second period, provided no restriction on capital tax rates. Here we use additively separable utility function to show that for such type preferences capital taxes are zero even along the transition path for the vintage specific tax case, but not zero when there is no ability to differentiate between vintages.

Assume utility function of the following form,

) ( 1 ) 1 , ( 1 l V c l c U + − = − − σ σ

For this type of utility function

σ σ σ υ υ σ υ υ υ υ υ = − =− = − − − − − − − − − t t t t t t c t t cc c t t c c c U c U M t t t t , , 1 , , , , , and υ σ υ υ υ υ υ − − = = − = − = − − − − − − − t t c cc l c c c c c c U U H H H t t t t t t t t t t , , , , 1 , 1 ,

So, for this type of utility function, c t t c

t

t M

M ,υ = +1,+1υ and the left-hand side of eq. (36) becomes simply 1 + t k R .

And for the vintage specific taxes, the condition c t t c t t Z Z,υ = +1,+1υ=0. Since, Mc Mc 1 , 1 0 ,

0 ≠ , the capital income tax is not necessarily equal to zero in period 1.

(30)

22

Proposition 4: With the vintage specific taxes, for the additively separable utility

functions, the optimal capital income tax rates are zero after the period t>1.

With vintage independent taxes, for the additively separable utility functions

c t t c t t M

M ,υ = +1,+1υ, but it is not necessarily that

c t t c t t Z Z,υ = +1,+1υ.

So for the additively separable utility functions with vintage independent taxes capital income taxes are not necessarily equal to zero along the transition path

3.6 Comparison with other Models

In the following table, I compare our results for optimal capital taxation with results in infinitely lived agent models and finitely lived overlapping generation models. I compare steady state capital tax for general utility functions, for additively separable utility functions and capital tax in the transition path for additively separable utility functions. The comparison is made for both uniform across generation and vintage specific tax cases.

(31)

23

Vintage Specific Tax Case

Infinitely-Lived Agent Model Infinitely-Lived OLG Model Finitely-Lived OLG Model In steady-state with general utility function 0 0 Not necessarily 0 In steady-state with additively separable utility function 0 0 0 In transition path with additively separable utility function 0 0 0

Vintage Independent Tax Case

Infinitely-Lived OLG Model Finitely-Lived OLG Model In steady-state with general utility function 0 Not necessarily 0 In steady-state with additively separable utility function 0 Not necessarily 0 In transition path with additively separable utility function

(32)

24

For vintage specific case with general utility function steady state capital income tax for our model are different from the results for finitely lived OLG model. For our model, in steady state general equilibrium expenditure elasticity is constant, however it may not be the case for finitely-lived OLG model.

Considering additively separable utility function, in the steady state two results will be the same, since general equilibrium expenditure elasticity for this type of functions are constant.

When government has restrictions on policy instruments, for our model this restriction does not matter, since in the steady state consumption over the individual’s life is constant. But this may not be the case for finitely lived OLG model, where the steady state consumption may not be constant. Even assuming additively separable functions, which stabilize general equilibrium expenditure elasticity does not change this result.

Along the transition path for both cases, general equilibrium expenditure elasticity is constant and for vintage specific tax case marginal rate of substitution between future consumption and present consumption across individuals of different vintages and marginal rate of substitution between consumption and labor across individuals of different vintages need not be constant, capital income tax could be set as zero.

(33)

25

However for uniform across generations tax case, it is constant, so capital taxes are not necessarily equal to zero.

Since our model converts to infinitely lived agent model, when population growth is equal to zero, n=0, infinitely lived agent model preserves all established properties of our model.

(34)

26

4 CONCLUSIONS

In this paper, we have shown that the optimal long-run tax on capital income is zero in infinitely lived overlapping generations economy for both cases when government has the ability to tax capital and labor income of individuals of different vintages differently and when it has no such an ability.

Our results are stronger than the ones for finitely lived OLG models. Without making any assumption about utility function, I get the optimality of non-taxing capital income in the long run, which is not necessarily so in finitely lived OLG models (Atkenson et.al (1999), Erosa and Gervais (1998)). And this results does not depend on the richness of government’s fiscal instruments, by which I mean ability of government, at any period to tax capital and labor income of individuals of different vintages differently.

For additively separable utility functions, if government has a rich set of fiscal instruments, then capital income tax is zero even in transition path. However,

(35)

27

restricting government to the uniform across generation tax may not lead to the same result.

(36)

28

References:

Ambler, Steve (2000), “Optimal Time-Consistent Fiscal Policy with Overlapping Generations”, European University Institute Working Paper No:111

Atkeson Andrew, Chari V.V. and Kehoe, Patrick J., (1999), “Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea”, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 22(3): 3-17

Atkinson, Anthony B.and Stiglitz, Joseph E., (1989) Lectures on Public Economics, 2nd ed.,London : McGraw-Hill

Aschauer, David A.. (1988), “The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal Policy”, Journal

of Money, Credit and Banking 20: 41-62

Auerbach, Alan J. and Kotlikoff, Lawrence J., (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Benhabib, Jess and Rustichini, Aldo. (1997) “ Optimal Taxes without Commitment”, Journal of Economic Theory 77: 231-259

Calvo, Guillermo A. and Obstfeld, Maurice, (1988), “Optimal Time- Consistent Fiscal Policy with Finite Families”, Econometrica 56:411-432

Chamley, Christophe (1985), “Efficient Taxation in a Stylized Model of Intertemporal General Equilibrium”, International Economic Review 26: 451-468

Chamley, Christophe (1986), “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives”, Econometrica 54: 607-622

(37)

29

Chari, V.V., Christiano, Lawrence J. and Kehoe, Patrick J.. (1991), ”Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Some Recent Results”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 23: 519-539

Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, Patrick J., (1993), “Sustainable Plans and Debt”, Journal of

Economic Theory 61: 230-261

Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, Patrick J., (1999), “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy” in Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, Vol. 1c, pp 1671-1745, Amsterdam: North-Holland

Erosa, Andres and Gervais, Martin (1998), “Optimal Taxation in Lyfe-Cycle Economies”, mimeo, University of Western Ontario

Jones, Larry E.; Manuelli, Rodolfo E. and Rossi, Peter E., (1997), “On the Optimal Taxation of Capital Income”, Journal of Economic Theory 73: 93-117

Judd, Kenneth L. (1985), “Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Forsight Model”, Journal of Public Economics 28: 59-83

Judd, Kenneth L. (1999), “Optimal Taxation and Spending in General Competitive Growth Models”, Journal of Public Economics 71: 1-26

Kydland, Finn E. and Prescott, Edward C., (1977), “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans”, Journal of Political Economy 85: 473-491

Lucas, Robert E. Jr. and Stokey, Nancy L., (1983), “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in an Economy without Capital”, Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 55-93

Ramsey, F.P.. (1927), “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation”, Economic

(38)

30

Phelan, Christopher and Stacchetti, Ennio. (2001), “Sequential Equilibria in a Ramsey Tax Model”, Econometrica , forthcoming

Weil, Phlippe. (1989), “Overlapping Families of Infinitely-Lived Agents”, Journal

Referanslar

Benzer Belgeler

However, while speculative domestic demand and economic bubbles drove rapid growth in periphery countries such as Spain, apparently anaemic growth in Germany was driven by exports

While the GDP per capita, inflation, the ratio of M2 to international reserves, real effective exchange rate and domestic credit provided by banking sector (% of GDP)

In this study, we aimed to produce functional polyvinyl alcohol (PVA) electrospun nanowebs containing essential oil; eugenol (EG), that have long-term durability and

One alternative approach, the entrapment of enzymes in conducting polymer matrices during electrochemical polymerization, is attracting great interest, because it

Purpose: The purpose of this study is to develop a wireless, flexible, ultra-thin, and passive radiofrequency-based MRI resonant fiducial marker, and to validate its feasibility in

In the present study, we have developed the microRNA Expression and Sequence Analysis Database, mESAdb, to provide a series of interactive analysis tools for testing the association

Colquhoun gibi, tarihselciliği “tarihin önemini vurgulayan bir teori” olarak kabul eden ve modernizmin tarihselci bilincine işaret eden Bozdoğan (2002, 64, 66),

Turist Rehberi, Turist Rehberliği Yönetmeliği’ne göre; turist rehberi ilgili yönetmelikte belirlenen usul ve esaslara uygun olarak rehberlik mesleğini icra etme yetkisini